Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-6tpvb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T21:12:21.444Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The sustainability of the commons: giving and receiving

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Nuria Osés-Eraso*
Affiliation:
Departamento de Economía, Universidad Pública de Navarra, Campus Arrosadia, Pamplona 31006, Spain
Montserrat Viladrich-Grau*
Affiliation:
Department of Business Administration (AEGERN), Universitat de Lleida, ETSEA, Rovira Roure 191, Lleida 25198, Spain

Abstract

This paper analyzes the use of a cost-free reward mechanism in the exploitation of a common property resource. We implement an experimental study involving a two-stages game where agents first decide resource appropriation and then have the opportunity to distribute cost-free bestowals. We observe that subjects link the two activities in such a way that appropriation determines the distribution of bestowals which in turn contributes maintaining low appropriation levels, thus avoiding the destruction of the common resource. Not all the potential bestowals are distributed, however.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2011 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Financial support by the Spanish Ministry of Science and Technology (project ECO2009-12836) is gratefully acknowledged. Montserrat Viladrich-Grau acknowledges the support of the Barcelona Graduate School of Economics Research Network and of the Government of Catalonia. We thank Frederic Udina, Jordi Brandts, Emilio Domínguez, Jorge Nieto and members of SEED research group for helpful comments and discussions. We also thank the helpful comments of two anonymous referees.

References

Andreoni, J., Harbaugh, W., & Vesterlund, L. (2003). The carrot or the stick: rewards, punishments and cooperation, American Economic Review, 93(3).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baland, J. M., & Platteau, J. P. (1996). Halting degradation of natural resources. Is there a role for rural communities? London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Baltagi, B. H. (2005). Econometric analysis of panel data (3rd edn.). West Sussex: Wiley.Google Scholar
Bochet, O., Page, T., & Putterman, L. (2006). Communication and punishment in voluntary contribution experiments. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 60, 1126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, J. P. (2007a). The demand for punishment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 62, 522542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, J. P. (2007b). Punishing free-rider: how group size affects mutual monitoring and the provision of public goods. Games and Economic Behavior, 60, 3151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casari, M. (2005). On the design of peer punishment experiments. Experimental Economics, 8, 107115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casari, M., & Plott, C. R. (2003). Decentralized management of common property resources: experiments with a centuries-old institution. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 51(2), 217247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chermak, J. M., & Krause, K. (2002). Individual response, information and intergenerational common pool problems. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43, 4770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cuevas, A., Febrero, M., & Fraiman, R. (2004). An anova test for functional data. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 47, 111122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A., Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2005). Driving forces of informal sanctions. Econometrica, 73(6), 20172030.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falkinger, J. (1996). Efficient private provision of public goods by rewarding deviations from average. Journal of Public Economics, 62, 413422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falkinger, J., Fehr, E., Gächter, S., & Winter-Ebmer, R. (2000). A simple mechanism for the efficient provision of public goods: experimental evidence. American Economic Review, 90(1), 147264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 90(4), 980994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2002). Altruistic punishment in humans, Nature, 415(10).CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fischbacher, U. (1999). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for readymade economic experiments. Reference Manual and Tutorial, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich.Google Scholar
Fischer, M. E., Irlenbusch, B., & Sadrieh, A. (2004). An intergenerational common pool resource experiment. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Floristán, A. (1995). Geografía de navarra. Pamplona: Diario de Navarra.Google Scholar
Greene, W. H. (1993). Econometric analysis (2nd edn.). New York: Macmillan Co.Google Scholar
Hey, D. H., Neugebauer, T., & Sadrieh, A. (2009). An experimental analysis of optimal renewable resource management: the fishery. Environmental and Resource Economics, 44, 263285.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iriarte Goñi, I. (1996). Bienes comunales y capitalismo agrario en Navarra: 1855-1935. Ministerio de Agricultura, Pesca y Alimentación, España.Google Scholar
Martínez, Lapuente (1990). Las Améscoas (Estudio histérico-etnográfico). Junta del Monte Limitaciones de las Améscoas y Gobierno de Navarra.Google Scholar
Masclet, D., Noussair, C., Tucker, S., & Villeval, M. (2003). Monetary and non-monetary punishment in the voluntary contributions mechanism. American Economic Review 93(1).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mason, C. F., & Phillips, O. R. (1997). Mitigating the tragedy of the commons through cooperation: an experimental evaluation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 34, 148172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moxnes, E. (2000). Not only the tragedy of the commons: misperceptions of feedback and policies for sustainable development. System Dynamics Review, 16(4), 325348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moxnes, E. (2004). Misperceptions of basic dynamics, the case of renewable resource management. System Dynamics Review, 20(2), 139162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nikiforakis, N., & Normann, H. T. (2008). A comparative statics analysis of punisment in public-good experiments. Experimental Economics, 11, 358369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oliver, P. (1980). Rewards and punishments as selective incentives for collective action: theoretical investigations. American Journal of Sociology, 85(6), 13561375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Osés-Eraso, N., Udina, F., & Viladrich-Grau, M. (2008). Environmental versus human-induced scarcity: do they trigger the same response? Environmental and Resource Economics, 40, 529550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Osés-Eraso, N., & Viladrich-Grau, M. (2007). On the sustainability of common property resources. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 53, 393410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons. The evolution of institutions for collective action. London: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E., Gardner, R., & Walker, J. (1994). Rules, games and common-pool resources. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E., Walker, J., & Gardner, R. (1992). Covenants with and without a sword: self-governance is possible. American Political Science Review 86(2).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sefton, M., Shupp, R., & Walker, J. (2007). The effects of rewards and sanctions in provision of public goods. Economic Inquiry, 45(4), 671690.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spagnolo, G. (1999). Social relations and cooperation in organizations. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 38, 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sutter, M., Haigner, S., & Kocher, M. G. (2010). Choosing the carrot or the stick? Endogenous institutional choice in social dilemma situations. Review of Economic Studies, 77, 15401566.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar