Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-hpxsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T12:48:21.983Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Status quo effects in fairness games: reciprocal responses to acts of commission versus acts of omission

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

James C. Cox*
Affiliation:
Experimental Economics Center and Department of Economics, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University, Atlanta, USA
Maroš Servátka
Affiliation:
MGSM Experimental Economics Laboratory, Macquarie Graduate School of Management, Sydney, Australia University of Economics in Bratislava, Bratislava, Slovakia
Radovan Vadovič
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Carleton University, Ottawa, Canada

Abstract

Both the law and culture distinguish between acts of commission that overturn the status quo and acts of omission that uphold it. This distinction is of central importance when it comes to reciprocal actions. A stylized fact of everyday life is that acts of commission elicit stronger reciprocal responses than do acts of omission. We report experiments that directly test whether this stylized fact characterizes behavior in controlled experiments. We compare reciprocal responses to both types of acts in experiments using binary, extensive form games. Across three experiments, we examine the robustness of our results to different ways in which the status quo can be induced in experiments. The data show a clear difference between effects of acts of commission and omission by first movers on reciprocal responses by second movers.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2016 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-016-9477-0) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Andreoni, J, Harbaugh, W, & Vesterlund, L (2003). The carrot or the stick: Rewards, punishment, and cooperation. American Economic Review, 93, 672685. 10.1257/000282803322157034CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, J, & Ritov, I (1994). Reference points and omission bias. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 59, 475498. 10.1006/obhd.1994.1070CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blount, S (1995). When social outcomes aren’t fair: The effect of causal attributions on preferences. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 63, 131144. 10.1006/obhd.1995.1068CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, GE, & Ockenfels, A (2000). ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review, 90, 166193. 10.1257/aer.90.1.166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J, & Charness, G (2011). The strategy versus the direct-response method: A survey of experimental comparisons. Experimental Economics, 14(3), 375398. 10.1007/s10683-011-9272-xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J, & Solà, C (2001). Reference Points and negative reciprocity in simple sequential games. Games and Economic Behavior, 36(2), 138157. 10.1006/game.2000.0818CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruni, L, Corazzini, L, & Stanca, L (2009). Testing theories of reciprocity: Do motivations matter?. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 71(2), 233245. 10.1016/j.jebo.2009.04.009Google Scholar
Cárdenas, JC, De Roux, N, Jaramillo, CR, & Martinez, LR (2014). Is it my money or not? An experiment on risk aversion and the house-money effect. Experimental Economics, 17(1), 4760. 10.1007/s10683-013-9356-xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlsson, F, He, H, & Martinsson, P (2013). Easy come, easy go: The role of windfall money in lab and field experiments. Experimental Economics, 16(2), 190207. 10.1007/s10683-012-9326-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G (2004). Attribution and reciprocity in an experimental labor market. Journal of Labor Economics, 22, 665688. 10.1086/383111CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Rabin, M (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 817869. 10.1162/003355302760193904CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cherry, T, Frykblom, P, & Shogren, J (2002). Hardnose the dictator. American Economic Review, 92, 12181221. 10.1257/00028280260344740CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, J (2002). House money effects in public good experiments. Experimental Economics, 5, 223231. 10.1023/A:1020832203804CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC (2004). How to identify trust and reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 2, 260281. 10.1016/S0899-8256(03)00119-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, & Deck, CA (2005). On the nature of reciprocal motives. Economic Inquiry, 43(3), 623635. 10.1093/ei/cbi043CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, Friedman, D, & Sadiraj, V (2008). Revealed altruism. Econometrica, 76, 3169. 10.1111/j.0012-9682.2008.00817.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, & Hall, D (2010). Trust with private and common property: Effects of stronger property right entitlements. Games, 1, 124. 10.3390/g1040527CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, Ostrom, E, Sadiraj, V, & Walker, JM (2013). Provision versus appropriation in symmetric and asymmetric social dilemmas. Southern Economic Journal, 79, 496512. 10.4284/0038-4038-2012.186CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, Ostrom, E, Walker, JM, Castillo, J, Coleman, E, Holahan, R, Schoon, M, & Steed, B (2009). Trust in private and common property experiments. Southern Economic Journal, 75, 957975.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, & Sadiraj, V (2007). On modeling voluntary contributions to public goods. Public Finance Review, 35, 311332. 10.1177/1091142106295756CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, Sadiraj, K, & Sadiraj, V (2008). Implications of trust, fear, and reciprocity for modelling economic behavior. Experimental Economics, 11(1), 124. 10.1007/s10683-006-9156-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Danková, K, & Servátka, M (2015). The house money effect and negative reciprocity. Journal of Economic Psychology, 48, 6071. 10.1016/j.joep.2015.02.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M, & Kirchsteiger, G (2004). A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47, 268298. 10.1016/j.geb.2003.06.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A, Fehr, E, & Fischbacher, U (2008). Testing theories of fairness—Intentions matter. Games and Economic Behavior, 62, 287303. 10.1016/j.geb.2007.06.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A, & Fischbacher, U (2006). A theory of reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 54, 293315. 10.1016/j.geb.2005.03.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E, & Schmidt, KM (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817868. 10.1162/003355399556151CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gärtner, M., & Sandberg, A. (2014). Is there an omission effect on prosocial behavior Beyond the Default Effect? SSE Working Paper Series in Economics No. 2014:1.Google Scholar
Grossman, Z (2014). Strategic ignorance and the robustness of social preferences. Management Science, 60(11), 26592665. 10.1287/mnsc.2014.1989CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrison, GW (2007). House money effects in public goods experiments: Comment. Experimental Economics, 10, 429437. 10.1007/s10683-006-9145-xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayashi, AT (2013). Occasionally libertarian: Experimental evidence of self-serving omission bias. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 29(3), 711733. 10.1093/jleo/ews046CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E, McCabe, K, Shachat, K, & Smith, V (1994). Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games and Economic Behavior, 7(3), 346380. 10.1006/game.1994.1056CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huck, S, Muller, W, & Normann, H (2001). Stackelberg beats Cournot: On collusion and efficiency in experimental markets. Economic Journal, 111, 749766. 10.1111/1468-0297.00658CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D, Knetsch, JL, & Thaler, R (1990). Experimental test of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. Journal of Political Economy, 98(6), 13251348. 10.1086/261737CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCabe, K, Rigdon, M, & Smith, V (2003). Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 52, 267275. 10.1016/S0167-2681(03)00003-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Offerman, T (2002). Hurting hurts more than helping helps. European Economic Review, 46(8), 14231437. 10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00176-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oxoby, RJ, & Spraggon, J (2008). Mine and yours: Property rights in dictator games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 65(3–4), 703713. 10.1016/j.jebo.2005.12.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritov, I, & Baron, J (1995). Outcome knowledge, regret, and omission bias. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 64(2), 119127. 10.1006/obhd.1995.1094CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutström, E, & Williams, M (2000). Entitlements and fairness: An experimental study of distributive preferences. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 43(1), 7589. 10.1016/S0167-2681(00)00109-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, W, & Zeckhauser, R (1988). Status quo bias in decision making. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1, 759. 10.1007/BF00055564CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, R, & Sauermann, H (1967). Die Strategiemethode zur Erforschung des eingeschränkt rationale Verhaltens im Rahmen eines Oligopolexperiments. Beiträge zur experimentellen Wirtschaftsforschung, Tübingen: Mohr 136168.Google Scholar
Spranca, M, Minsk, E, & Baron, J (1991). Omission and commission in judgment and choice. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 27, 76105. 10.1016/0022-1031(91)90011-TCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strahilevitz, M, & Loewenstein, G (1998). The effect of ownership history on the valuation of objects. Journal of Consumer Research, 25, 276289. 10.1086/209539CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, RH, & Johnson, EJ (1990). Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: The effects of prior outcomes on risky choice. Management Science, 36, 643660. 10.1287/mnsc.36.6.643CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A, & Kahneman, D (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297323. 10.1007/BF00122574CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Cox et al. supplementary material

Cox et. al. supplementary material
Download Cox et al. supplementary material(File)
File 81.5 KB