Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-sk4tg Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T08:16:18.104Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Playing the trust game with other people’s money

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Ola Kvaløy*
Affiliation:
University of Stavanger, Stavanger, Norway
Miguel Luzuriaga
Affiliation:
University of Stavanger, Stavanger, Norway

Abstract

We experimentally investigate to what extent people trust and honor trust when they are playing with other people’s money (OPM). We adopt the well-known trust game by Berg et al. (in Games Econ. Behav. 10:122–142, 1995), with the difference that the trustor (sender) who sends money to the trustee (receiver) does this on behalf of a third party. We find that senders who make decisions on behalf of others do not behave significantly different from senders in our baseline trust game who manage their own money. But receivers return significantly less money when senders send a third party’s money. As a result, trust is only profitable in the baseline trust game, but not in the OPM treatment. The treatment effect among the receivers is gender specific. Women return significantly less money in OPM than in baseline, while there is no such treatment effect among men. Moreover, women return significantly less than men in the OPM treatment.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2013 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic Supplementary Material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-013-9386-4) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

We would like to thank the Editor, two referees and Jim Andreoni, Alexander Cappelen, Gary Charness, Kristoffer Eriksen, Åshild Johnsen, Klaus Mohn, Mari Rege, Bettina Rochenbach and participants at the Nordic conference on Behavioral and Experimental Economics in Lund, the International Meeting on Experimental and Behavioral Economics in Castellón, the ESA Meeting in Xiamen and the ESA meeting in Tucson for helpful comments and discussions. Financial support from the Norwegian Research Council is greatly appreciated.

References

Agranov, M., Bisin, A., & Schotter, A. (2010). Other people’s money: an experimental study of the impact of the competition for funds. Working Paper, New York University.Google Scholar
Bartling, B., & Fischbacher, U. (2012). Shifting the blame: on delegation and responsibility. Review of Economic Studies, 79(1), 6787. 10.1093/restud/rdr023CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellemare, C., & Kröger, S. (2007). On representative social capital. European Economic Review, 5, 183202. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2006.03.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Ner, A., Kong, F., Putterman, L., & Magan, D. (2004). Reciprocity in a two-part dictator game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 53(3), 333352. 10.1016/j.jebo.2002.12.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 122142. 10.1006/game.1995.1027CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohnet, I. Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2007). Why women and men trust others. Economics and psychology. A promising new cross-disciplinary field, Cambridge and London: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Bohnet, I., & Zeckhauser, R. (2004). Trust, risk and betrayal. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 55(4), 467484. 10.1016/j.jebo.2003.11.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity and competition. The American Economic Review, 90, 166193. 10.1257/aer.90.1.166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J., & Sola, C. (2001). Reference points and negative reciprocity in simple sequential games. Games and Economic Behavior, 36, 138157. 10.1006/game.2000.0818CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchan, N., Croson, R., & Solnick, S. (2008). Trust and gender: an examination of behavior and beliefs in the investment game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 68, 466476. 10.1016/j.jebo.2007.10.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chakravarty, S., Harrison, G., Haruvy, E., & Rutström, E. (2011). Are you risk averse over other people’s money?. Southern Economic Journal, 77(4), 901913. 10.4284/0038-4038-77.4.901CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Jackson, M. (2008). The role of responsibility in strategic risk-taking. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 69, 241247. 10.1016/j.jebo.2008.10.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Levine, D. I. (2007). Intention and stochastic outcomes: an experimental study. The Economic Journal, 117, 10511072. 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02066.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 817869. 10.1162/003355302760193904CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chaudhuri, A., & Gangadharan, L. (2007). An experimental analysis of trust and trustworthiness. Southern Economic Journal, 73(4), 959985.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, K., & Sefton, M. (2001). The sequential prisoner’s dilemma: evidence on reciprocation. The Economic Journal, 111, 5168. 10.1111/1468-0297.00588CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coffman, L. C. (2011). Intermediation reduces punishment (and reward). American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 3(4), 77106.Google Scholar
Cox, J. C., & Deck, C. (2006). When are women more generous than men?. Economic Inquiry, 44, 587598. 10.1093/ei/cbj042CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Croson, R., & Buchan, N. (1999). Gender and culture: international experimental evidence from trust games. The American Economic Review, 89(2), 386391. 10.1257/aer.89.2.386CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Croson, R., & Gneezy, U. (2009). Gender differences in preferences. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 127. 10.1257/jel.47.2.448CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M., & Kirchsteiger, G. (2004). A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47, 268298. 10.1016/j.geb.2003.06.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, C., & Grossman, P. (1996). The relative price of fairness: gender differences in a punishment game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 30, 143158. 10.1016/S0167-2681(96)00854-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, C., & Wilson, R. (2004a). Conditional trust: sex, race and facial expressions in a trust game. Working Paper, Virginia Tech.Google Scholar
Eckel, C., & Wilson, R. (2004b). Whom to trust? Choice of partner in a trust game. Working Paper, Virginia Tech.Google Scholar
Eriksen, K., & Kvaløy, O. (2010). Myopic investment management. Review of Finance, 14(3), 521542. 10.1093/rof/rfp019CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A., & Fischbacher, U. (2006). A theory of reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 54, 293315. 10.1016/j.geb.2005.03.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A., Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2003). On the nature of fair behavior. Economic Inquiry, 41(1), 2026. 10.1093/ei/41.1.20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Fairness and retaliation: the economics of reciprocity. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159181. 10.1257/jep.14.3.159CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817868. 10.1162/003355399556151CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., Kirchsteiger, G., & Riedl, A. (1993). Does fairness prevent market clearing? An experimental investigation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(2), 437460. 10.2307/2118338CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fershtman, C., & Gneezy, U. (2001). Strategic delegation: an experiment. The Rand Journal of Economics, 32(2), 352368. 10.2307/2696414CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U. (2007). Z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamman, J. R., Loewenstein, G., & Weber, R. A. (2010). Self-interest through delegation: an additional rationale for the principal-agent relationship. The American Economic Review, 100(4), 18261846. 10.1257/aer.100.4.1826CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Innocenti, A., & Pazienza, M. (2006). Altruism and gender in the trust game. Working paper, University of Sienna.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCabe, K., Smith, V. Gigerenzer, G., & Selten, R. (2000). Goodwill accounting in economic exchange. Bounded rationality: the adaptive toolbox, Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
McCabe, K., Rigdon, M., & Smith, V. (2003). Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 52(2), 267275. 10.1016/S0167-2681(03)00003-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Migheli, M. (2007). Trust, gender, and social capital: experimental evidence from three western European countries. Working Paper, University of Turin and Catholic University of Leuven.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Offerman, T. (2002). Hurting hurts more than helping helps. European Economic Review, 46, 14231437. 10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00176-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. The American Economic Review, 83(5), 12811302.Google Scholar
Reynolds, D., Joseph, J., & Sherwood, R. (2009). Risky shift versus cautious shift: determining differences in risk taking between private and public management decision-making. Journal of Business Economics Research, 7(1), 6378.Google Scholar
Schwieren, C., & Sutter, M. (2008). Trust in cooperation or ability? An experimental study on gender differences. Economics Letters, 99(3), 494497. 10.1016/j.econlet.2007.09.033CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slonim, R., & Guillen, P. (2010). Gender selection discrimination: evidence from a trust game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 76, 385405. 10.1016/j.jebo.2010.06.016CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snijders, C., & Keren, G. (2001). Do you trust? Whom do you trust? When do you trust?. Advances in Group Processes, 18, 129160. 10.1016/S0882-6145(01)18006-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Song, F. (2008). Trust and reciprocity behavior and behavioral forecasts: individuals versus group-representatives. Games and Economic Behavior, 62(2), 675696. 10.1016/j.geb.2007.06.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Kvaløy and Luzuriaga supplementary material

Appendix
Download Kvaløy and Luzuriaga supplementary material(File)
File 12.7 KB