Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-f9bf7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T05:54:57.121Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Payment schemes in infinite-horizon experimental games

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Katerina Sherstyuk*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Hawaii at Manoa, 2424 Maile Way, Honolulu, HI 96822, USA
Nori Tarui*
Affiliation:
University of Hawaii at Manoa, Honolulu, USA
Tatsuyoshi Saijo*
Affiliation:
Osaka University, Osaka, Japan

Abstract

We consider payment schemes in experiments that model infinite-horizon games by using random termination. We compare paying subjects cumulatively for all periods of the game; with paying subjects for the last period only; with paying for one of the periods, chosen randomly. Theoretically, assuming expected utility maximization and risk neutrality, both the cumulative and the last period payment schemes induce preferences that are equivalent to maximizing the discounted sum of utilities. The last period payment is also robust under different attitudes toward risk. In comparison, paying subjects for one of the periods chosen randomly creates a present-period bias. We further provide experimental evidence from infinitely repeated prisoners’ dilemma games that supports the above theoretical predictions.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2012 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic Supplementary Material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-012-9323-y) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Aoyagi, M., & Frechette, G. (2009). Collusion as public monitoring becomes noisy: experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Theory, 144, 11351165. 10.1016/j.jet.2008.10.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azrieli, Y., & Chambers, C. Healy, P. J. (2011). Incentive compatibility across decision problems. Mimeo, Ohio State University. November.Google Scholar
Blonski, M., & Spagnolo, G. (2001). Prisoners’ other dilemma. Mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blonski, M., Ockenfels, P., & Spagnolo, G. (2011). Equilibrium selection in the repeated prisoner’s dilemma: axiomatic approach and experimental evidence. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 3, 164192. 10.1257/mic.3.3.164Google Scholar
Camerer, C., Weigelt, K. Friedman, D., & Rust, J. (1993). Convergence in experimental double auctions for stochastically lived assets. The double auction market: theories, institutions and experimental evaluations, Redwood City: Addison-Wesley 355396.Google Scholar
Charness, G., & Genicot, G. (2009). Informal risk-sharing in an infinite-horizon experiment. Economic Journal, 119, 796825. 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2009.02248.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandrasekhar, A., & Xandri, J. P. (2011). A note on payments in experiments of infinitely repeated games with discounting. Mimeo, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. December.Google Scholar
Chandrasekhar, A., & Kinnan, C. Larreguy, H. (2012). Informal insurance, social networks, and saving access: evidence from a framed field experiment. Mimeo, Northwestern University. April.Google Scholar
Cox, J. C. (2010). Some issues of methods, theories, and experimental designs. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 73, 2428. 10.1016/j.jebo.2009.01.014CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cubitt, R., Starmer, C., & Sugden, R. (1998). On the validity of the random lottery incentive system. Experimental Economics, 1, 115131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dal Bo, P. (2005). Cooperation under the shadow of the future: experimental evidence from infinitely repeated games. American Economic Review, 95(5), 15911604. 10.1257/000282805775014434Google Scholar
Dal Bo, P., & Frechette, G. (2011). The evolution of cooperation in infinitely repeated games: experimental evidence. American Economic Review, 101, 411429. 10.1257/aer.101.1.411CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, D. D., & Holt, C. A. (1993). Experimental economics, Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffy, J., & Ochs, J. (2009). Cooperative behavior and the frequency of social interactions. Games and Economic Behavior, 66, 785812. 10.1016/j.geb.2008.07.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engle-Warnick, J., & Slonim, R. (2006). Inferring repeated-game strategies from actions: evidence from trust game experiments. Economic Theory, 28, 603632. 10.1007/s00199-005-0633-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engle-Warnick, J., & Slonim, R. (2006). Learning to trust in indefinitely repeated games. Games and Economic Behavior, 54, 95114. 10.1016/j.geb.2004.10.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D., Rand, D., & Dreber, A. (2012). Slow to anger and fast to forgive: cooperation in an uncertain world. American Economic Review, 102(2), 720749. 10.1257/aer.102.2.720CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1991). Game theory, Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hey, J., & Lee, J. (2005). Do subjects separate (or are they sophisticated)?. Experimental Economics, 8, 233265. 10.1007/s10683-005-1465-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holt, C. A. (1986). Preference reversals and the independence axiom. American Economic Review, 76(3), 508515.Google Scholar
Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92(5), 16441655. 10.1257/000282802762024700CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lei, V., & Noussair, C. (2002). An experimental test of an optimal growth model. American Economic Review, 92(3), 549570. 10.1257/00028280260136246CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murnighan, J. K., & Roth, A. (1983). Expecting continued play in prisoner’s dilemma games. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 27(2), 279300. 10.1177/0022002783027002004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nowak, M. A., & Sigmund, K. (1993). A strategy of win-stay, lose-shift that outperforms tit-for-tat in prisoner’s dilemma. Nature, 364, 5658. 10.1038/364056a0CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Offerman, T., Potters, J., & Verbon, H. A. A. (2001). Cooperation in an overlapping generations experiment. Games and Economic Behavior, 36(2), 264275. 10.1006/game.2000.0816CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A., & Murnighan, J. K. (1978). Equilibrium behavior and repeated play of the prisoner’s dilemma. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 17, 189198. 10.1016/0022-2496(78)90030-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schotter, A., & Sopher, B. (2003). Social learning and convention creation in inter-generational games: an experimental study. Journal of Political Economy, 111(3), 498529. 10.1086/374187CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sherstyuk, K., Tarui, N., & Ravago, M. Saijo, T. (2009). Games with dynamic externalities and climate change. Mimeo, University of Hawaii at Manoa. http://www2.hawaii.edu/~katyas/pdf/climate-change_draft050209.pdf.Google Scholar
Sherstyuk, K., Tarui, N., & Ravago, M. Saijo, T. (2011). Payment schemes in random-termination experimental games. University of Hawaii Working Paper 11-2. http://www.economics.hawaii.edu/research/workingpapers/WP_11-2.pdf.Google Scholar
Starmer, C., & Sugden, R. (1991). Does the random-lottery incentive system elicit true preferences? An experimental investigation. American Economic Review, 81(4), 971978.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Sherstyuk et al. supplementary material

Sherstyuk et. al. supplementary material
Download Sherstyuk et al. supplementary material(File)
File 855.9 KB