Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-sk4tg Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T22:10:30.495Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Learning under supervision: an experimental study

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Raghuram Iyengar*
Affiliation:
Wharton School, 3730 Walnut Street, 700Jon M. Huntsman Hall, Philadelphia, 19104 PA, USA
Andrew Schotter*
Affiliation:
New York University, 269 Mercer St. 7th Floor, New York, NY 10003, USA

Abstract

In many market environments, for example in investment banking, salesforce management and others, workers and supervisors work closely as a team. Workers are paid a fixed salary and supervisors determine any raises, which are typically dependent on how well the organization does. In such scenarios, a supervisor who constantly offers suggestions can create a problem—typically a worker cannot ignore his supervisor's advice, yet if such advice is wrong and is followed, it will only decrease firm profits. We conduct a laboratory experiment to address a question critical for such settings—does the relationship between advisor and worker interfere with the learning abilities of the worker? The answer is a resounding no. In fact, subjects who have a supervisor advising them and whose advice is costly to ignore actually learn better than those with an advisor whose advice can be ignored. An even more striking result is that advisees as well as advisors in both these conditions learn better than subjects with no advisors. Our result can be attributed to the presence of advice and has direct relevance to learning in many environments.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2007 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10683-007-9164-2) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Athey, S., Avery, C., & Zemsky, P. (2000). Mentoring and diversity. The American Economic Review, 90, 765786.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bornstein, G., & Gneezy, U. (2002). Price competition between teams. Experimental Economics, 5, 2938.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bornstein, G., & Yaniv, I. (1998). Individual and group behavior in the ultimatum game: are groups more “rational” players?. Experimental Economics, 1, 101108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bull, C., Schotter, A., & Weigelt, K. (1987). Tournament and piece rates: an experimental study. Journal of Political Economy, 95, 133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chi, M., Bassok, M., Lewis, M., Reimann, P., & Glaser, R. (1989). Self-explanations: how students study and use examples in learning to solve problems. Cognitive Science, 15, 145182.Google Scholar
Cooper, D. J., & Kagel, J. H. (2005). Are two heads better than one? Team versus individual play in signaling games. American Economic Review, 95(3), 477509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J. C., & Hayne, S. C. (2006). Barking up the right tree: are small groups rational agents?. Experimental Economics, 9(3), 209222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duarte, N. T., Goodson, J.R., & Klich, N. R. (1993). How do i like thee? Let me appraise the ways. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 14, 239249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duarte, N. T., Goodson, J. R., & Klich, N. R. (1994). Effects of dyadic quality and duration on performance appraisal. The Academy of Management Journal, 37, 499521.Google Scholar
Eisenhardt, K. (1989). Agency theory: assessment and review. Academy of Management Review, 14, 5774.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferguson-Hessler, M., & de Jong, T. (1990). Studying physics texts: differences in study processes between good and poor solvers. Cognition and Instruction, 7, 4154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
John, G., & Weitz, B. (1989). Salesforce compensation: an empirical investigation of factors related to use of salary versus incentive compensation. Journal of Marketing Research, 16, 114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaworksi, B. J., & Kohli, A. K. (1991). Supervisory feedback: alternative types and their impact on salesperson's performance and satisfaction. Journal of Marketing Research, 28, 190201.Google Scholar
Kocher, M., & Sutter, M. (2005). The decision maker matters. Individual versus team behavior in experimental beauty-contest games. Economic Journal, 115, 200223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kohli, A. K., Shervani, T. A., & Challagalla, G. N. (1998). Learning and performance orientation of salespeople: the role of supervisors. Journal of Marketing Research, 35, 263274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krishna, V., & Morgan, J. (2001). A model of expertise. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 747775.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lerner, J. S., & Tetlock, P. E. (1994). Accountability and social cognition. In Ramachandran, V. S. (Ed.), Encyclopedia of human behavior (Vol. 1, pp. 30983121).Google Scholar
Lerner, J. S., & Tetlock, P. E. (1999). Accounting for the effects of accountability. Psychological Bulletin, 125(2), 255275.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lounamaa, P. H., & March, J. G. (1987). Adaptive coordination of a learning team. Management Science, 33, 107123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merlo, A., & Schotter, A. (1999). A surprise-quiz view of learning in economic experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 28, 2554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merlo, A., & Schotter, A. (2003). Learning by not doing: an experimental investigation of observational learning. Games and Economic Behavior, 42, 116136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nagel, R. (1995). Experimental results on interactive competitive guessing. American Economic Review, 85, 13131326.Google Scholar
Newey, W. K., & West, K.D. (1987). A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica, 55, 703708.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oliver, R. L., & Anderson, E. (1994). An empirical test of the consequences of behavior and outcome- based sales control systems. Journal of Marketing, 58, 5367.Google Scholar
Ottaviani, M., & Sorensen, P. N. (2003). Professional advice: the theory of reputational cheap talk. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Perrow, C. (1986). Complex organizations. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Prendergast, C. (1993). A Theory of ‘yes men’. American Economic Review, 757770.Google Scholar
Pressley, M., Wood, E., Woloshyn, V., Martin, V., King, A., & Menke, D. (1992). Encouraging mindful use of prior knowledge: attempting to construct explanatory answers facilitates learning. Educational Psychologist, 27, 91109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Radner, R., & Marschak, J. (1972). Economic theory of teams. New Haven: Cowles Foundation and Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Schotter, A., & Weigelt, K. (1992). Asymmetric tournaments, equal opportunity laws and affirmative action: some experimental results. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 511539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sujan, H., Weitz, B. A., & Kumar, N. (1994). Learning orientation, working smart and effective selling. Journal of Marketing, 58, 3952.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tetlock, P. E. (1983). Accountability and complexity of thought. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 45, 7483.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, R. (2003). Learning with no feedback in a competitive guessing game. Games and Economic Behavior, 44, 134144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Iyengar and Schotter supplementary material

Iyengar and Schotter supplementary material 1
Download Iyengar and Schotter supplementary material(File)
File 44.5 KB
Supplementary material: File

Iyengar and Schotter supplementary material

Iyengar and Schotter supplementary material 2
Download Iyengar and Schotter supplementary material(File)
File 41 KB