Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-nzzs5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T17:59:08.728Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Learning to Accept in Ultimatum Games: Evidence from an Experimental Design that Generates Low Offers

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

John A. List
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Central Florida, Orlando, FL 32816-1400
Todd L. Cherry
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Appalachian State University, Boone, NC 28608-2051

Abstract

Focusing on responder behavior, we report panel data findings from both low and high stakes ultimatum bargaining games. Whereas Slonim and Roth (1998) find that offers are rejected fairly equally across rounds in both low and high stakes games, we find that learning does take place, but only when there is sufficient money on the table. The disparate results can be reconciled when one considers the added power that our experimental design provides-detecting subtle temporal differences in responder behavior requires a data generation process that induces a significant number of proportionally low offers.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2000 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Bolton, G. (1991). “A Comparative Model of Bargaining: Theory and Evidence.” American Economic Review. 81, 10961136.Google Scholar
Chamberlain, G. (1980). “Analysis of Covariance with Qualitative Data.” Review of Economic Studies. 47, 225238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cherry, T.L. and List, J.A. (2000). “Self-interest in Bargaining Games when Initial Wealth is Earned.” Working paper, University of Central Florida.Google Scholar
Conlisk, J. (1996). “Why Bounded Rationality?Journal of Economic Literature. 34, 669700.Google Scholar
Forsythe, R., Horowitz, J., Savin, N.E., and Sefton, M. (1994). “Replicability, Fairness and Pay in Experiments with Simple Bargaining Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 6(3), 347369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D. and Levine, D. (1997). “Measuring Players’ Losses in Experimental Games.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 112, 507536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guth, W., Schmittberger, R., and Schwartz, R. (1982). “An Experimental Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 3, 367388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., McCabe, K.A., Shachat, K., and Smith, V.L. (1994). “Preferences, Property Rights and Anonymity in Bargaining Games.” Games and Economic Behavior. 7(3), 346380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., McCabe, K.A., and Smith, V.L. (1996a). “On Expectations and the Monetary Stakes in Ultimatum Games.” International Journal of Game Theory. 25(3), 289302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., McCabe, K.A., and Smith, V.L. (1996b). “Social Distance and Other-Regarding Behavior in Dictator Games.” American Economic Review. 86(3), 653660.Google Scholar
List, J.A. and Lucking-Reilly, D. (forthcoming). “Demand Reduction in a Multi-Unit Auction: Evidence from a Sportscard Field Experiment.American Economic Review.Google Scholar
List, J.A. and Shogren, J.F. (1998). “Experimental Calibration of the Difference Between Actual and Hypothetical Reported Valuations.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 37(2), 193205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A.E. and Erev, I. (1995). “Learning in Extensive-Form Games: Experimental Data and Simple Dynamic Models in the Intermediate Term.” Games and Economic Behavior 8, 164212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar