Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-f9bf7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T21:13:45.221Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Information and beliefs in a repeated normal-form game

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

David N. Danz*
Affiliation:
Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin, Berlin, Germany
Dietmar Fehr*
Affiliation:
Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin, Berlin, Germany
Dorothea Kübler*
Affiliation:
Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin, Berlin, Germany Technische Universität Berlin, Berlin, Germany

Abstract

We study beliefs and actions in a repeated normal-form game. Using a level-k model of limited strategic reasoning and allowing for other-regarding preferences, we classify action and belief choices with regard to their strategic sophistication and study their development over time. In addition to a baseline treatment with common knowledge of the game structure, feedback about actions in the previous period and random matching, we run treatments (i) with fixed matching, (ii) without information about the other player’s payoffs, and (iii) without feedback about previous play. In all treatments with feedback, we observe more strategic play (increasing by 15 percent) and higher-level beliefs (increasing by 18 percent) over time. Without feedback, neither beliefs nor actions reach significantly higher levels of reasoning (with increases of 2 percentage points for actions and 6 percentage points for beliefs). The levels of reasoning reflected in actions and beliefs are highly consistent, but less so for types with lower levels of reasoning.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2012 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic Supplementary Material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-012-9317-9) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

We are grateful for valuable comments of the editor, Jacob Goeree, and two anonymous referees whose critical comments helped us to improve the paper. We also wish to thank Britt Grosskopf, Kyle Hyndman, Rajiv Sarin, Roberto Weber, Georg Weizsäcker, Axel Werwatz and seminar participants at the Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin, EUI Florence, CRC 649 Workshop 2007, ESA World Meeting 2007, IMEBE 2008, VfS Annual Meeting 2008 and Econometric Society Meetings 2009 for valuable comments. We are indebted to Jana Stöver and Susanne Thiel for their help with running the experiments. Financial support from the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft via CRC 649 Economic Risk is gratefully acknowledged.

References

Anderson, S. P., Goeree, J. K., & Holt, C. A. (1998). A theoretical analysis of altruism and decision error in public goods games. Journal of Public Economics, 70, 297323. 10.1016/S0047-2727(98)00035-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Agranov, M., & Caplin, A. Tergiman, C. (2010). The process of choice in guessing games. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D., & Welch, I. (1992). A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational cascades. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 9921026. 10.1086/261849CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanco, M., Engelmann, D., Koch, A., & Normann, H.-T. (2010). Belief elicitation in experiments: is there a hedging problem?. Experimental Economics, 13, 412438. 10.1007/s10683-010-9249-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C., Ho, T., & Chong, J.-K. (2004). A cognitive hierarchy model of games. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 861898. 10.1162/0033553041502225CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, D. J., & Kagel, J. H. (2005). Are two heads better than one? Team versus individual play in signaling games. American Economic Review, 95, 477509. 10.1257/0002828054201431CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costa-Gomes, M. A., Crawford, V., & Broseta, B. (2001). Cognition and behavior in normal-form games: an experimental study. Econometrica, 69, 11931235. 10.1111/1468-0262.00239CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costa-Gomes, M. A., & Weizsäcker, G. (2008). Stated beliefs and play in normal-form games. Review of Economic Studies, 75, 729762. 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2008.00498.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J. C., Friedman, D., & Gjerstad, S. (2007). A tractable model of reciprocity and fairness. Games and Economic Behavior, 59, 1745. 10.1016/j.geb.2006.05.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edgeworth, F. (1881). Mathematical psychics: an essay on the application of mathematics to the moral sciences, London: Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Hyndman, K., Özbay, E. Y., & Schotter, A. Ehrblatt, W. Z. (2012). Convergence: an experimental study of teaching and learning in repeated games. Journal of the European Economic Association (forthcoming).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, D., & Kübler, D. Danz, D. (2008). Information and beliefs in a repeated normal-form game, SFB 649 Working Paper No. 2008–026.Google Scholar
Fischbacher, Urs (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goeree, J. K., Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Private costs and public benefits: unraveling the effects of altruism and noisy behavior. Journal of Public Economics, 83, 255276. 10.1016/S0047-2727(00)00160-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goeree, J. K., & Holt, C. A. (2004). A model of noisy introspection. Games and Economic Behavior, 46, 365382. 10.1016/S0899-8256(03)00145-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B. Kremer, K., & Macho, V. (2004). An online recruitment system for economic experiments. Forschung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen 2003, GWDG Bericht 63, Göttingen: Ges. für Wiss. Datenverarbeitung, 7993.Google Scholar
Holyoak, K. J., & Bower, G. H. (1985). The pragmatics of analogical transfer. The psychology of learning and motivation, New York: Academic Press 5987.Google Scholar
Johnson-Laird, P. N., & Rabbitt, P. (2009). Reasoning. Inside psychology: a science over 50 years, Oxford: Oxford University Press 167177.Google Scholar
Kalai, E., & Lehrer, E. (1993). Subjective equilibrium in repeated games. Econometrica, 61, 12311240. 10.2307/2951500CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nagel, R. (1995). Unraveling in guessing games: an experimental study. American Economic Review, 85, 13131326.Google Scholar
Nyarko, Y., & Schotter, A. (2002). An experimental study of belief learning using elicited beliefs. Econometrica, 70, 9711005. 10.1111/1468-0262.00316CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oechssler, J., & Schipper, B. (2006). Can you guess the game you are playing?. Games and Economic Behavior, 43, 137152. 10.1016/S0899-8256(02)00549-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rey-Biel, P. (2009). Equilibrium play and best response to (stated) beliefs in constant sum games. Games and Economic Behavior, 65, 572585. 10.1016/j.geb.2008.03.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rick, S., & Weber, R. (2010). Meaningful learning and transfer of learning in games played repeatedly without feedback. Games and Economic Behavior, 68, 716730. 10.1016/j.geb.2009.10.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutstrom, E., & Wilxoc, N. (2009). Stated beliefs versus inferred beliefs: a methodological inquiry and experimental test. Games and Economic Behavior, 69, 616632. 10.1016/j.geb.2009.04.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sidowski, J. B. (1957). Reward and punishment in the minimal social situation. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 54, 318326. 10.1037/h0047119CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stahl, D. O., & Wilson, P. W. (1995). On players’ models of other players: theory and experimental evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 218254. 10.1006/game.1995.1031CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Terracol, A., & Vaksmann, J. (2009). Dumbing down rational players: learning and teaching in an experimental game. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 70, 5471. 10.1016/j.jebo.2009.02.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, R. (2003). “Learning” with no feedback in a competitive guessing game. Games and Economic Behavior, 44, 134144. 10.1016/S0899-8256(03)00002-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Danz et al. supplementary material

Appendix
Download Danz et al. supplementary material(File)
File 179.2 KB