Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-9klzr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T22:16:15.322Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Heterogeneity and the Voluntary Provision of Public Goods

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Kenneth S. Chan
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, McMaster University, Hamilton, Ontario, L8S 4M4, Canada
Robert Moir
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of New Brunswick, PO. Box 5050, Saint John, New Brunswick, E2L 4L5, Canada
R. Andrew Muller
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, McMaster University, Hamilton, Ontario, L8S 4M4, Canada
Stuart Mestelman*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, McMaster University, Hamilton, Ontario, L8S 4M4, Canada
*
*Corresponding author. email: [email protected]

Abstract

We investigate the effects of heterogeneity and incomplete information on aggregate contributions to a public good using the voluntary contribution mechanism. The non-linear laboratory environment has three-person groups as partners under varying conditions of information and communication. Bergstrom, Blum and Varian predict that increasing heterogeneity will have no effect on aggregate contributions in a no-communication environment. Ledyard conjectures a positive effect of incomplete information, a negative effect of heterogeneity, and a positive interaction of heterogeneity and incomplete information. We find that incomplete information has a small but significant negative effect. Heterogeneity has a positive effect on aggregate contributions, but its effects interact unexpectedly with communication. In a no-communication environment, heterogeneity in two dimensions (endowment and preferences) increases contributions substantially while heterogeneity in a single dimension (endowment or preferences) has little effect. In the communication environment we find the reverse. We also find a positive interaction between heterogeneity and incomplete information. Thus we reject the Bergstrom, Blume and Varian invariance result and provide mixed evidence on Ledyard's conjectures.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 1999 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Andreoni, J. (1993). “An Experimental Test of the Public Goods Crowding-Out Hypothesis.” American Economic Review. 83, 13171327.Google Scholar
Bagnoli, M. and McKee, M. (1991). “Voluntary Contribution Games: Efficient Private Provision of Public Goods.” Economic Inquiry. 29, 351366.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bardhan, P. (1993). “Symposium on Management of Local Commons.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 7, 8792.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergstrom, T.C., Blume, L.E., and Varian, H.R. (1986). “On the Private Provision of Public Goods.” Journal of Public Economics. 29, 2549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brookshire, D., Coursey, D., and Redington, D. (1993). “Special Interests and the Voluntary Provision of Public Goods.” Discussion Paper. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico.Google Scholar
Chan, K.S., Godby, R., Mestelman, S., and Muller, R.A. (1998). “Crowding Out Voluntary Contributions to Public Goods.” Working Paper 98-03, Hamilton, Canada: McMaster University.Google Scholar
Chan, K.S., Godby, R., Mestelman, S., and Muller, R.A. (1997). “Equity Theory and the Voluntary Provision of Public Goods.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 32, 349364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chan, K.S., Mestelman, S., Moir, R., and Muller, R.A. (1996). “The Voluntary Provision of Public Goods Under Varying Income Distributions.” Canadian Journal of Economics. 29, 5469.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, J., Isaac, R.M., Schatzberg, J., and Walker, J.M. (1994). “Heterogenous Demand for Public Goods: Behavior in the Voluntary Contributions Mechanism.” Public Choice. 85, 249266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckathorn, D.D. (1993). “Collective Action and Group Heterogeneity: Voluntary Provision Versus Selective Incentives.” American Sociological Review. 58, 329350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hackett, S.C. (1992). “Heterogeneity and the Provision of Governance for Common-Pool Resources.” Journal of Theoretical Politics. 4, 325342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hackett, S.C., Schlager, E., and Walker, J.M. (1994). “The Role of Communication in Resolving Commons Dilemmas: Experimental Evidence with Heterogeneous Appropriators.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 27, 99126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, R.M. and Walker, J.M. (1988). “Communication and Free-Riding Behavior: The Voluntary Contribution Mechanism.” Economic Inquiry. 24, 585608.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kanbur, R. (1992). “Heterogeneity, Distribution, and Cooperation in Common Property Resource Management.” Policy Research Working Paper WPS 844, Washington, D.C.: World Bank.Google Scholar
Ledyard, J. (1995). “Public Goods: A Survey of Experimental Research.” In Kagel, John and Roth, Alvin (eds.), The Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 111194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marwell, G. and Ames, R. (1979). “Experiments on the Provision of Public Goods I: Resources, Interest, Group Size, and the Free-Rider Problem.” American Journal of Sociology. 84, 13351360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marwell, G. and Ames, R. (1980). “Experiments on the Provision of Public Goods II: Provision Points, Stakes, Experience and the Free-Rider Problem.” American Journal of Sociology. 85, 926937.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marwell, G., Oliver, P.E., and Prahl, R. (1988). “Social Networks and Collective Actions: A Theory of the Critical Mass III.” American Journal of Sociology. 94, 502534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moir, R. (1996). The Analysis of Cooperation in Collective Action Games: Experimental Evidence. Ph.D. Thesis. Hamilton, Canada: McMaster University.Google Scholar
Moir, R. (1998). “A Monte Carlo Analysis of the Fisher Randomization Technique: Reviving Randomization for Experimental Economists.” Experimental Economics. 1, 87100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muller, R.A. and Vickers, M. (1996). “Communication in a Common Pool Resource Environment with Probabilistic Destruction.” Working Paper 96-06, Hamilton, Canada: McMaster University.Google Scholar
Oliver, P.E., Marwell, G., and Teixeira, R. (1985). “A Theory of the Critical Mass I: Interdependence, Group Heterogeneity, and the Production of Collective Action.” American Journal of Sociology. 91, 522556.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M. (1983). “The Political Economy of Comparative Growth Rates.” In Mueller, Dennis (ed.), The Political Economy of Growth. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 752.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1992). Crafting Institutions for Self-Governing Irrigation Systems. San Francisco, California: ICS Press.Google Scholar
Rapoport, A. and Suleiman, R. (1993). “Incremental Contribution in Step-Level Public Goods Games with Asymmetric Players.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. 55, 171194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, J.M., Gardner, R., and Ostrom, E. (1990). “Rent Dissipation in Limited Access Common-Pool Resource Environments: Experimental Evidence.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 19, 203211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar