Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-7g5wt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T13:28:00.769Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Expected utility theory and prospect theory: one wedding and a decent funeral

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Glenn W. Harrison*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, College of Business Administration, University of Central Florida, Orlando, FL, USA
E. Elisabet Rutström*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, College of Business Administration, University of Central Florida, Orlando, FL, USA

Abstract

Choice behavior is typically evaluated by assuming that the data is generated by one latent decision-making process or another. What if there are two (or more) latent decision-making processes generating the observed choices? Some choices might then be better characterized as being generated by one process, and other choices by the other process. A finite mixture model can be used to estimate the parameters of each decision process while simultaneously estimating the probability that each process applies to the sample. We consider the canonical case of lottery choices in a laboratory experiment and assume that the data is generated by expected utility theory and prospect theory decision rules. We jointly estimate the parameters of each theory as well as the fraction of choices characterized by each. The methodology provides the wedding invitation, and the data consummates the ceremony followed by a decent funeral for the representative agent model that assumes only one type of decision process. The evidence suggests support for each theory, and goes further to identify under what demographic domains one can expect to see one theory perform better than the other. We therefore propose a reconciliation of the debate over two of the dominant theories of choice under risk, at least for the tasks and samples we consider. The methodology is broadly applicable to a range of debates over competing theories generated by experimental and non-experimental data.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Economic Science Association 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We thank the U.S. National Science Foundation for research support under grants NSF/IIS 9817518, NSF/HSD 0527675 and NSF/SES 0616746; Ryan Brossette, Harut Hovsepyan, David Millsom and Bob Potter for research assistance; and Steffen Andersen, Vince Crawford, Curt Eaton, John Hey, Peter Kennedy, Jan Kmenta, Peter Wakker, two referees, and numerous seminar participants for helpful comments. Supporting data and instructions are stored at the ExLab Digital Library at http://exlab.bus.ucf.edu.

References

Andersen, S., Harrison, G. W., & Rutström, E. E. (2006a). Choice behavior, asset integration, and natural reference points (Working Paper 06-07). Department of Economics, College of Business Administration, University of Central Florida.Google Scholar
Andersen, S., Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., & Rutström, E. E. (2006b). Dual criteria decisions (Working Paper 06-11). Department of Economics, College of Business Administration, University of Central Florida.Google Scholar
Andersen, S., Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., & Rutström, E. E. (2008). Eliciting risk and time preferences. Econometrica, 76(3), 583618.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Araña, J. E., & León, C. J. (2005). Flexible mixture distribution modeling of dichotomous choice contingent valuation with heterogeneity. Journal of Environmental Economics & Management, 50(1), 170188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. C. (1970). A method for discriminating between models. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B, 32, 323344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bardsley, N., & Moffatt, P. G. (2007). The experimetrics of public goods: inferring motivations from contributions. Theory and Decision, 62(2), 161193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(1), 7592.Google Scholar
Benhabib, J., & Bisin, A. (2005). Modeling internal commitment mechanisms and self-control: a neuroeconomics approach to consumption-saving decisions. Games and Economic Behavior, 52, 460492.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandstätter, E., Gigerenzer, G., & Hertwig, R. (2006). The priority heuristic: making choices without trade-offs. Psychological Review, 113(2), 409432.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bruhin, A., Fehr-Duda, H., & Epper, T. F. (2007). Risk and rationality: uncovering heterogeneity in probability distortion (Working Paper 0705). Socioeconomic Institute, University of Zurich.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F. (1995). Individual decision making. In Kagel, J. H. & Roth, A. E. (Eds.), The handbook of experimental economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F., & Ho, T.-H. (1994). Violations of the betweeness axiom and nonlinearity in probability. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 8, 167196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cherry, T. L., Frykblom, P., & Shogren, J. F. (2002). Hardnose the dictator. American Economic Review, 92(4), 12181221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clarke, K. A. (2003). Nonparametric model discrimination in international relations. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 47(1), 7293.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clarke, K. A. (2007). A simple distribution-free test for non-nested model selection. Political Analysis, 15(3), 347363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, J. D. (2005). The vulcanization of the human brain: a neural perspective on interactions between cognition and emotion. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(4), 324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conte, A., Hey, J. D., & Moffatt, P. G. (2007). Mixture models of choice under risk (Discussion Paper No. 2007/06). Department of Economics and Related Studies, University of York.Google Scholar
Cox, D. R. (1961). Tests of separate families of hypotheses. In Charatsis, E. G. (Ed.), Proceedings of the fourth Berkeley symposium on mathematical statistics and probability (Vol. 1, pp. 105123). Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Cox, D. R. (1962). Further results on tests of separate families of hypotheses. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B, 24, 406424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J.C., & Sadiraj, V. (2006). Small- and large-stakes risk aversion: implications of concavity calibration for decision theory. Games & Economic Behavior, 56(1), 4560.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davidson, R., & MacKinnon, J. G. (1993). Estimation and inference in econometrics. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
El-Gamal, M. A., & Grether, D. M. (1995). Are people Bayesian? Uncovering behavioral strategies. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 90(432), 11371145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Everitt, B. S. (1996). An introduction to finite mixture distributions. Statistical Methods in Medical Research, 5, 107127.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fudenberg, D., & Levine, D. K. (2006). A dual-self model of impulse control. American Economic Review, 96(5), 14491476.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
George, J.G., Johnson, L.T., & Rutström, E. E. (2007). Social preferences in the face of regulatory change. In Cherry, T., Kroll, S., & Shogren, J. F. (Eds.), Experimental methods, environmental economics. Oxford: Routledge.Google Scholar
Geweke, J., & Keane, M. (1999). Mixture of normals probit models. In Hsio, C., Lahiri, K., Lee, L.-F., & Pesaran, M. H. (Eds.), Analysis of panel and limited dependent variables: a volume in honor of G.S. Maddala. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Goodman, L. A. (1974a). The analysis of systems of qualitative variables when some of the variables are unobservable: Part I. A modified latent structure approach. American Journal of Sociology, 79, 11791259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodman, L. A. (1974b). Exploratory latent structure analysis using both identifiable and unidentifiable models. Biometrika, 61, 215231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grether, D. M., & Plott, C. R. (1979). Economic theory of choice and the preference reversal phenomenon. American Economic Review, 69(4), 623648.Google Scholar
Haigh, M., & List, J. A. (2005). Do professional traders exhibit myopic loss aversion? An experimental analysis. Journal of Finance, 60(1), 523534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harless, D. W., & Camerer, C. F. (1994). The predictive utility of generalized expected utility theories. Econometrica, 62, 12511289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrison, G. W., & List, J. A. (2004). Field experiments. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(4), 10131059.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrison, G. W., & Rutström, E. E. (2008). Risk aversion in the laboratory. In Cox, J. C. & Harrison, G. W. (Eds.), Research in experimental economics: Vol. 12. Risk aversion in experiments. Bingley: Emerald.Google Scholar
Harrison, G. W., Humphrey, S. J., & Verschoor, A. (2005). Choice under uncertainty: evidence from Ethiopia, India and Uganda (Working Paper 05-29). Department of Economics, College of Business Administration, University of Central Florida.Google Scholar
Haruvy, E., Stahl, D. O., & Wilson, P. W. (2001). Modeling and testing for heterogeneity in observed strategic behavior. Review of Economics and Statistics, #3(1), 146157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckman, J., & Singer, B. (1984). A method for minimizing the impact of distributional assumptions in econometric models for duration data. Econometrica, 52(2), 271320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hey, J. D., & Orme, C. (1994). Investigating generalizations of expected utility theory using experimental data. Econometrica, 62(6), 12911326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92(5), 16441655.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hosmer, D. W., & Lemeshow, S. (2000). Applied logistic regression (2nd edn.). New York: Wiley.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hurley, T. M., & Shogren, J. F. (2005). An experimental comparison of induced and elicited beliefs. Journal of Risk & Uncertainty, 30(2), 169188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, L. T., Rutström, E. E., & George, J. G. (2006). Income distribution preferences and regulatory change in social dilemmas. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 61(2), 181198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirman, A. P. (1992). Whom or what does the representative individual represent? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6(2), 117136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Köbberling, V., & Wakker, P. P. (2005). An index of loss aversion. Journal of Economic Theory, 122, 119131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kumbhakar, S. C., & Lovell, C. A. K. (2000). Stochastic frontier analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liang, K.-Y, & Zeger, S. L. (1986). Longitudinal data analysis using generalized linear models. Biometrika, 73, 1322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
List, J. A. (2002). Preference reversals of a different kind: the more is less phenomenon. American Economic Review, 92, 16361643.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
List, J. A. (2003). Does market experience eliminate market anomalies. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 4171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
List, J. A. (2004). Neoclassical theory versus prospect theory: evidence from the marketplace. Econometrica, 72(2), 615625.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loomes, G., & Sugden, R. (1998). Testing different stochastic specifications of risky choice. Economica, 65, 581598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lopes, L. L. (1995). Algebra and process in the modeling of risky choice. In Busemeyer, J. R., Hastie, R., & Medin, D. L. (Eds.), Decision making from a cognitive perspective. San Diego: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Lopes, L.L., & Oden, G. C. (1999). The role of aspiration level in risky choice: a comparison of cumulative prospect theory and SP/A theory. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 43, 286313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luce, R. D., & Suppes, P. (1965). Preference, utility, and subjective probability. In Luce, R. D., Bush, R. R., & Galanter, E. (Eds.), Handbook of mathematical psychology (Vol. 3, pp. 249410). New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Marschak, J. (1960). Binary choice constraints on random utility indications. In Arow, K. (Ed.), Stanford symposium on mathematical models in the social sciences. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
McLachlan, G., & Peel, D. (2000). Finite mixture models. New York: Wiley.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oehlert, G. W. (1992). A note on the delta method. The American Statistician, 46(1), 2729.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Papke, L. E., & Wooldridge, J. M. (1996). Econometric methods for fractional response variables with an application to 401(K) plan participation rates. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 11, 619632.3.0.CO;2-1>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pearson, K. (1894). Contribution to the mathematical theory of evolution. Philosophical Transactions A, 185, 71110.Google Scholar
Pesaran, M. H. (1981). Pitfalls of testing non-nested hypotheses by the Lagrange multiplier method. Journal of Econometrics, 17, 323331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pollak, R. A., & Wales, T. J. (1991). The likelihood dominance criterion: a new approach to model selection. Journal of Econometrics, 47, 227242.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prelec, D. (1998). The probability weighting function. Econometrica, 66(3), 497527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quandt, R. E. (1974). A comparison of methods for testing nonnested hypotheses. Review of Economics and Statistics, 56, 9299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rogers, W. H. (1993). Regression standard errors in clustered samples. Stata Technical Bulletin, 13, 1923.Google Scholar
Schoemaker, P. (1982). The expected utility model: its variants, purposes, evidence and limitations. Journal of Economic Literature, 20(2), 529563.Google Scholar
Stahl, D. O. (1996). Boundedly rational rule learning in a guessing game. Games and Economic Behavior, 16, 303330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stahl, D. O. (1998). Is step- j thinking an arbitrary modelling restriction or a fact of human nature? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 37, 3351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stahl, D. O., & Wilson, P. W. (1995). On players’ models of other players: theory and experimental evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 218254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Starmer, C. (2000). Developments in non-expected utility theory: the hunt for a descriptive theory of choice under risk. Journal of Economic Literature, 38, 332382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Titterington, D. M., Smith, A. F. M., & Makov, U. E. (1985). Statistical analysis of finite mixture distributions. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Train, K. E. (2003). Discrete choice methods with simulation. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representations of uncertainty. Journal of Risk & Uncertainty, 5, 297323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vermunt, J. K., & Magidson, J. (2003). Latent class models for classification. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 41,531-537.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vuong, Q. H. (1989). Likelihood ratio tests for model selection and non-nested hypotheses. Econometrica, 57(2), 307333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, M., & Fischbeck, P. S. (2004). Incorporating framing into prospect theory modeling: a mixture- model approach. Journal of Risk & Uncertainty, 29(2), 181197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Werner, M. (1999). Allowing for zeros in dichotomous choice contingent valuation models. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 17, 479486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, R. L. (2000). A note on robust variance estimation for cluster-correlated data. Biometrics, 56, 645646.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wooldridge, J. (2003). Cluster-sample methods in applied econometrics. American Economic Review (Papers & Proceedings), 93, 133138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wu, G., & Gonzalez, R. (1996). Curvature of the probability weighting function. Management Science, 42, 16761690.CrossRefGoogle Scholar