Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-nzzs5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T16:14:56.983Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Do people who care about others cooperate more? Experimental evidence from relative incentive pay

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Pablo Hernandez-Lagos*
Affiliation:
New York University Abu Dhabi, Abu Dhabi, United Arab Emirates
Dylan Minor
Affiliation:
Northwestern University, Evanston, IL, USA
Dana Sisak
Affiliation:
Erasmus University Rotterdam, Rotterdam, The Netherlands Tinbergen Institute, Rotterdam, The Netherlands

Abstract

We experimentally study ways in which social preferences affect individual and group performance under indefinitely repeated relative incentives. We also identify the mediating role that communication and leadership play in generating these effects. We find other-regarding individuals tend to depress efforts by 15% on average. However, selfish individuals are nearly three times more likely to lead players to coordinate on minimal efforts when communication is possible. Hence, the other-regarding composition of a group has complex consequences for organizational performance.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2017 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-017-9512-9) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Abreu, D (1988). On the theory of infinitely repeated games with discounting. Econometrica, 56(2), 383396. 10.2307/1911077CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Athey, S, & Bagwell, K (2008). Collusion with persistent cost shocks. Econometrica, 76(3), 493540. 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2008.00845.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, R Gabszewicz, JJ, Richard, JF, & Wolsey, LA (1990). Nash equilibria are not self-enforcing. Economic decision making: Games, econometrics and optimisation, Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Aumann, R, Maschler, M, & Stearns, RE (1968). Repeated games of incomplete information: An approach to the non-zero-sum case, Ch IV, Princeton: Mathematica ST-143.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J, & Miller, J (2002). Giving according to GARP: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70(2), 737753. 10.1111/1468-0262.00302CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoyagi, M, & Fréchette, G (2009). Collusion as public monitoring becomes noisy: Experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Theory, 144(3), 11351165. 10.1016/j.jet.2008.10.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arbak, E, & Villeval, MC (2013). Voluntary leadership: Motivation and influence. Social Choice and Welfare, 40(3), 635662. 10.1007/s00355-011-0626-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backes-Gellner, U, & Pull, K (2013). Tournament compensation systems, employee heterogeneity, and firm performance. Human Resource Management, 52(3), 375398. 10.1002/hrm.21535CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bandiera, O, Barankay, I, & Rasul, I (2005). Social preferences and the response to incentives: Evidence from personnel data. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(3), 917962.Google Scholar
Blonski, M., & Spagnolo, G. (2004). Prisoners’ other dilemma. SSE/EFI working paper 437.Google Scholar
Bolton, P, Brunnermeier, MK, & Veldkamp, L (2013). Leadership, coordination, and corporate culture. The Review of Economic Studies, 80(2), 512537. 10.1093/restud/rds041CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonatti, A, Cisternas, G, & Toikka, J (2016). Dynamic oligopoly with incomplete information. The Review of Economic Studies.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, S, & Polania-Reyes, S (2012). Economic incentives and social preferences: Substitutes or complements?. Journal of Economic Literature, 50(2), 368425. 10.1257/jel.50.2.368CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruttel, L., & Fischbacher, U. (2010). Taking the initiative. What motivates leaders? TWI Research Paper Series 61, Thurgauer Wirtschaftsinstitut, Universität Konstanz.Google Scholar
Cabral, L, Ozbay, EY, & Schotter, A (2014). Intrinsic and instrumental reciprocity: An experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior, 87, 100121. 10.1016/j.geb.2014.05.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casas-Arce, P, & Martínez-Jerez, FA (2009). Relative performance compensation, contests, and dynamic incentives. Management Science, 55(8), 13061320. 10.1287/mnsc.1090.1021CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, R, DeJong, DV, Forsythe, R, & Ross, TW (1992). Communication in coordination games. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 739771. 10.2307/2118488CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, JD, & Kühn, K-U (2014). Communication, renegotiation, and the scope for collusion. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 6(2), 24778.Google Scholar
Dal Bó, P (2005). Cooperation under the shadow of the future: Experimental evidence from infinitely repeated games. The American Economic Review, 5, 15911604.Google Scholar
Dal Bó, P, & Fréchette, GR (2011). The evolution of cooperation in infinitely repeated games: Experimental evidence. The American Economic Review, 101(1), 411429. 10.1257/aer.101.1.411CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dal Bó, P., & Fréchette, G. R. (2014). On the determinants of cooperation in infinitely repeated games: A survey. Available at SSRN 2535963.Google Scholar
DellaVigna, S (2009). Psychology and economics: Evidence from the field. Journal of Economic Literature, 47(2), 315372. 10.1257/jel.47.2.315CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dreber, A, Fudenberg, D, & Rand, DG (2014). Who cooperates in repeated games: The role of altruism, inequity aversion, and demographics. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 98, 4155. 10.1016/j.jebo.2013.12.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffy, J, & Ochs, J (2009). Cooperative behavior and the frequency of social interaction. Games and Economic Behavior, 66(2), 785812. 10.1016/j.geb.2008.07.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Embrey, M. S., Fréchette, G. R., & Stacchetti, E. (2013). An experimental study of imperfect public monitoring: Renegotiation proofness vs efficiency. Working paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Escobar, JF, & Toikka, J (2013). Efficiency in games with Markovian private information. Econometrica, 81(5), 18871934. 10.3982/ECTA9557Google Scholar
Erkal, N, Gangadharan, L, & Nikiforakis, N (2011). Relative earnings and giving in a real-effort experiment. American Economic Review, 101(3), 33303348. 10.1257/aer.101.7.3330CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farrell, J, & Rabin, M (1996). Cheap talk. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(3), 103118. 10.1257/jep.10.3.103CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E, & Fischbacher, U (2002). Why social preferences matter—The impact of non-selfish motives on competition, cooperation and incentives. The Economic Journal, 112, C1C33. 10.1111/1468-0297.00027CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U, & Gächter, S (2010). Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments. The American Economic Review, 100(1), 541556. 10.1257/aer.100.1.541CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisman, R, Kariv, S, & Markovits, D (2007). Individual preferences for giving. American Economic Review, 97(5), 18581876. 10.1257/aer.97.5.1858CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fonseca, MA, & Normann, HT (2012). Explicit vs. tacit collusion—The impact of communication in oligopoly experiments. European Economic Review, 56(8), 17591772. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2012.09.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forges, F (1992). Repeated games of incomplete information: Non-zero-sum. Handbook of game theory with economic applications, 1, 155177. 10.1016/S1574-0005(05)80009-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, J (1971). A noncooperative equilibrium for supergames. The Review of Economic Studies, 38, 112. 10.2307/2296617CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D, & Maskin, E (1986). The folk theorem in repeated games with discounting or incomplete information. Econometrica, 54, 533554. 10.2307/1911307CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D, Rand, DG, & Dreber, A (2012). Slow to anger and fast to forgive: Cooperation in an uncertain world. American Economic Review, 102(2), 720749. 10.1257/aer.102.2.720CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gächter, S, Nosenzo, D, Renner, E, & Sefton, M (2012). Who makes a good leader? Cooperativeness, optimism and leading-by-example. Economic Inquiry, 50(4), 867879. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2010.00295.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gächter, S, & Thöni, C (2005). Social learning and voluntary cooperation among like-minded people. Journal of the European Economic Association, 3(2–3), 303314. 10.1162/jeea.2005.3.2-3.303CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gächter, S., & Renner, E. (2005). Leading by example in the presence of free rider incentives. CeDEx discussion paper, University of Nottingham.Google Scholar
Güth, W, Levati, MV, Sutter, M, & Van Der Heijden, E (2007). Leading by example with and without exclusion power in voluntary contribution experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 91(5), 10231042. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2006.10.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hermalin, B (1998). Towards an economic theory of leadership: Leading by example. American Economic Review, 88(5), 11881206.Google Scholar
Hermalin, B Gibbons, R, & Roberts, J (2012). Leadership and corporate culture. Handbook of organizational economics, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Holt, CA, & Laury, SK (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92(5), 16441655. 10.1257/000282802762024700CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kidd, M, Nicholas, A, & Rai, B (2013). Tournament outcomes and prosocial behaviour. Journal of Economic Psychology, 39, 387401. 10.1016/j.joep.2013.05.011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kocher, MG, Pogrebna, G, & Sutter, M (2013). Other-regarding preferences and management styles. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 88, 109132. 10.1016/j.jebo.2013.01.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kőszegi, B (2014). Behavioral contract theory. Journal of Economic Literature, 52(4), 10751118. 10.1257/jel.52.4.1075CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koukoumelis, A, Levati, MV, & Weisser, J (2012). Leading by words: A voluntary contribution experiment with one-way communication. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 81(2), 379390. 10.1016/j.jebo.2011.11.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, DM, & Tsuchiya, M (1986). Corporate culture and economic theory. Technology, innovation, and business strategy, Tokyo: Nippon Keizai Shumbunsha Press.Google Scholar
Ledyard, J Kagel, J, & Roth, A (1994). Public goods: A survey of experimental research. Handbook of experimental economics, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Loch, CH, & Wu, Y (2008). Social preferences and supply chain performance: An experimental study. Management Science, 54(11), 18351849. 10.1287/mnsc.1080.0910CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meidinger, C., & Villeval, M. C. (2002). Leadership in teams: Signaling or reciprocating?. GATE working paper, 10-03, Lyon.Google Scholar
Moxnes, E, & van der Heijden, E (2003). The effect of leadership in a public bad experiment. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 47(6), 773795. 10.1177/0022002703258962CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palfrey, T, & Rosenthal, H (1994). Repeated play, cooperation and coordination: An experimental study. Review of Economic Studies, 61(3), 545565. 10.2307/2297903CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riyanto, Y, & Zhang, J (2013). The impact of social comparison of ability on pro-social behaviour. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 47, 3746. 10.1016/j.socec.2013.08.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rey-Biel, P., Sheremeta, R., & Uler, N. (2012). (Bad) luck or (lack of) effort? Sharing rules in the US and Europe. Working paper.Google Scholar
Rotemberg, J, & Saloner, G (1993). Leadership styles and incentives. Management Science, 39, 12991318. 10.1287/mnsc.39.11.1299CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotemberg, J, & Saloner, G (2000). Visionaries, managers and strategic direction. Rand Journal of Economics, 31, 693716. 10.2307/2696355CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seelya, B, Van Huyck, J, & Battalio, R (2007). Credible assignments can improve efficiency in laboratory public goods games. Journal of Public Economics, 89(8), 14371455. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2004.02.010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sherstyuk, K, Tarui, N, & Saijo, T (2013). Payment schemes in infinite-horizon experimental games. Experimental Economics, 16(1), 125153. 10.1007/s10683-012-9323-yCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Hernandez-Lagos et al. supplementary material

Online Appendix: Do People Who Care About Others Cooperate More? Experimental Evidence from Relative Incentive Pay
Download Hernandez-Lagos et al. supplementary material(File)
File 936.4 KB