Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-g9frx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T22:31:09.079Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Directional behavioral spillover and cognitive load effects in multiple repeated games

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Tracy Xiao Liu*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Tsinghua University, Beijing, China
Jenna Bednar*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI 48109, USA
Yan Chen*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Tsinghua University, Beijing, China School of Information, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI 48109, USA
Scott Page*
Affiliation:
Departments of Political Science and Economics, Center for the Study of Complex Systems, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI 48109, USA

Abstract

In this study, we use a novel design to test for directional behavioral spillover and cognitive load effects in a set of multiple repeated games. Specifically, in our experiment, each subject plays a common historical game with two different matches for 100 rounds. After 100 rounds, the subject switches to a new game with one match and continues playing the historical game with the other match. This design allows us to identify the direction of any behavioral spillover. Our results show that participants exhibit both behavioral spillover and cognitive load effects. First, for pairs of Prisoners’ Dilemma and Alternation games, we find that subjects apply strategies from the historical game when playing the new game. Second, we find that those who participate in a Self Interest game as either their historical or new game achieve Pareto efficient outcomes more often in the Prisoners’ Dilemma and Alternation games compared to their control counterparts. Overall, our results show that, when faced with a new game, participants use strategies that reflect both behavioral spillover and cognitive load effects.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2018 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-018-9570-7) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Abreu, D, & Rubinstein, A (1988). The structure of nash equilibrium in repeated games with finite automata. Econometrica, 56(6), 12591281. 10.2307/1913097CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahn, T-K, Ostrom, E, Schmidt, D, Shupp, R, & Walker, J (2001). Cooperation in PD games: Fear, greed, and history of play. Public Choice, 106, 137155. 10.1023/A:1005219123532CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albert, M, Guth, W, & Kirchler, E (2007). Are we nice(r) to nice(r) people?—An experimental analysis. Experimental Economics, 10(1), 5369. 10.1007/s10683-006-9131-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, M (1994). The contingent governance of teams: Analysis of institutional complementarity. International Economic Review, 35(3), 657676. 10.2307/2527079CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, M (2001). Toward a comparative institutional analysis, Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press 10.7551/mitpress/6867.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bednar, J, Chen, Y, Liu, TX, & Page, SE (2012). Behavioral spillovers and cognitive load in multiple games: An experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior, 74(1), 1231. 10.1016/j.geb.2011.06.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bednar, J, Jones-Rooy, A, & Page, SE (2015). Choosing a future based on the past: Institutions, behavior, and path dependence. European Journal of Political Economy, 40, 312322. 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2015.09.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bednar, J, & Page, SE (2007). Can game(s) theory explain culture?: The emergence of cultural behavior in multiple games. Rationality and Society, 19(1), 6597. 10.1177/1043463107075108CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bednar, J, & Page, SE (2018). When order affects performance: Culture, behavioral spillovers, and institutional path dependence. American Political Science Review, 112(1), 8298. 10.1017/S0003055417000466CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bednar, J, Page, SE, & Toole, J (2012). Revised-path dependence. Political Analysis, 20(2), 146156. 10.1093/pan/mpr051CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bettenhausen, K, & Murnighan, JK (1985). The emergence of norms in competitive decision-making groups. Administrative Science Quarterly, 30, 350372. 10.2307/2392667CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bettenhausen, K, & Murnighan, JK (1991). The development of an intragroup norm and the effects of interpersonal and structural challenges. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36, 2035. 10.2307/2393428CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boeker, W (1989). Strategic change: The effects of founding and history. Academy of Management Journal, 32(3), 489515.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, T, & Gangadharan, L (2013). Cooperation spillovers and price competition in experimental markets. Economic Inquiry, 51(3), 17151730. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2012.00486.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, TN, Lau, S-HP, & Mui, V-L (2013). Learning, teaching, and turn taking in the repeated assignment game. Economic Theory, 54(2), 335357. 10.1007/s00199-012-0718-yCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, T, Savikhin, A, & Sheremeta, R (2012). Behavioral spillovers in coordination games. European Economic Review, 56(3), 233245. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2011.09.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Y, & Plott, CR (1996). The Groves–Ledyard mechanism: An experimental study of institutional design. Journal of Public Economics, 59, 335364. 10.1016/0047-2727(95)01506-XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, DJ, & Kagel, JH (2008). Learning and transfer in signaling games. Economic Theory, 34(3), 415439. 10.1007/s00199-006-0192-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Devetag, G (2005). Precedent transfer in coordination games: An experiment. Economics Letters, 89(2), 227232. 10.1016/j.econlet.2005.05.038CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffy, J., & Fehr, D. (2018) (Forthcoming). Equilibrium selection in similar repeated games: Experimental evidence on the role of precedents. Experimental Economics.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engle-Warnick, J, & Slonim, RL (2006). Inferring repeated-game strategies from actions: Evidence from trust game experiments. Economic Theory, 28(3), 603632. 10.1007/s00199-005-0633-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorina, MP, & Plott, CR (1978). Committee decisions under majority rule: An experimental study. The American Political Science Review, 72(2), 575598. 10.2307/1954111CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiment. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, JW (1971). A non-cooperative equilibrium for supergames. The Review of Economic Studies, 38(1), 112. 10.2307/2296617CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilboa, I, & Schmeidler, D (1995). Case-based decision theory. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 605639. 10.2307/2946694CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanaki, N, Sethi, R, Erev, I, & Peterhansl, A (2005). Learning strategies. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 56(4), 523542. 10.1016/j.jebo.2003.12.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kagel, JH Kagel, JH, & Roth, AE (1995). Auctions: A survey of experimental research. Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kagel, JH, & Levin, D (1986). The winner’s curse and public information in common value auctions. American Economic Review, 76, 894920.Google Scholar
Knez, M, & Camerer, C (2000). Increasing cooperation in prisoner’s dilemmas by establishing a precedent of efficiency in coordination games. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 82, 194216. 10.1006/obhd.2000.2882CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lei, V, Noussair, CN, & Plott, CR (2001). Nonspeculative bubbles in experimental asset markets: Lack of common knowledge of rationality vs. actual irrationality. Econometrica, 69(4), 831859. 10.1111/1468-0262.00222CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCarter, MW, Samak, AC, & Sheremeta, RM (2014). Divided loyalists or conditional cooperators? Creating consensus about cooperation in multiple simultaneous social dilemmas. Group & Organization Management, 39(6), 744771. 10.1177/1059601114551606CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mengel, F, & Sciubba, E (2010). Extrapolation and structural similarity in games. Economics Letters, 125(3), 381385. 10.1016/j.econlet.2014.10.015CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, DC (2005). Understanding the process of economic change, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press 10.1515/9781400829484CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, SE (2006). Path dependence. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 1, 87115. 10.1561/100.00000006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plott, CR (1982). Industrial organization theory and experimental economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 20(4), 14851527.Google Scholar
Plott, CR (1994). Experimental methods in economics and political science: The design and testing of policy options. Human Dimensions Quarterly, 1(2), 58.Google Scholar
Plott, CR, Rullère, J-L, & Villeval, MC (2011). Introduction to the special issue on behavioral and experimental public economics. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 13(5), 631637. 10.1111/j.1467-9779.2011.01514.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, RD (1993). Making democracy work: Civic traditions in modern Italy, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, A (1986). Finite automata play the repeated prisoner’s dilemma. Journal of Economic Theory, 39(1), 8396. 10.1016/0022-0531(86)90021-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, L (2001). Analogies, adaptations, and anomalies. Journal of Economic Theory, 97(2), 320366. 10.1006/jeth.2000.2754CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Savikhin, A, & Sheremeta, RM (2013). Simultaneous decision-making in competitive and cooperative environments. Economic Inquiry, 51(2), 13111323. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2012.00474.x (Forthcoming)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shannon, CE (1948). A mathematical theory of communication. Bell System Technical Journal, 27, 379423. 10.1002/j.1538-7305.1948.tb01338.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Huyck, JB, Battalio, RC, & Beil, RO (1991). Strategic uncertainty, equilibrium selection, and coordination failure in average opinion games. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(3), 885910. 10.2307/2937932CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Liu et al. supplementary material

Appendix B. Experimental Instructions
Download Liu et al. supplementary material(File)
File 29.6 KB