Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-g9frx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T22:27:25.926Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Communication and coordination in the laboratory collective resistance game

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Timothy N. Cason*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Krannert School of Management, Purdue University, 403 W. State St., West Lafayette, IN 47907-2056, USA
Vai-Lam Mui*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Monash University, P.O. Box 11E, Clayton, Victoria 3800, Australia

Abstract

This paper presents a laboratory collective resistance (CR) game to study how different forms of non-binding communication among responders can help coordinate their collective resistance against a leader who transgresses against them. Contrary to the predictions of analysis based on purely self-regarding preferences, we find that non-binding communication about intended resistance increases the incidence of no transgression even in the one-shot laboratory CR game. In particular, we find that the incidence of no transgression increases from 7 percent with no communication up to 25-37 percent depending on whether communication occurs before or after the leader's transgression decision. Responders’ messages are different when the leaders can observe them, and the leaders use the observed messages to target specific responders for transgression.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2007 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic Supplementary Material The online version of this article (http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10683-007-9181-1) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Acemoglu, D., Robinson, J., & Verdier, T. (2004). Kleptocracy and divide-and-rule: A model of personal rule. Journal of the European Economic Association Papers and Proceedings, 2, 162192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battalio, R., Samuelson, L., & Van Huyck, J. (2001). Optimization incentives and coordination failure in laboratory stag hunt games. Econometrica, 69, 749764.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bosman, R., & van Winden, F. (2002). Emotional hazard in a power-to-take experiment. Economic Journal, 112, 147169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, T., & Mui, V.-L. (2007). Coordinating collective resistance through communication and repeated interaction. Working Paper. Purdue and Monash Universities.Google Scholar
Charness, G., & Dufwenberg, M. (2006). Promises and partnership. Econometrica, 74, 15791601.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 817869.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, D., & Kagel, J. (2005). Are two heads better than one? Team versus individual play in signaling games. American Economic Review, 95, 477509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2004). Third-party punishment and social norms. Evolution and Human Behavior, 25, 6387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for readymade economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, R. (2001). Trust in social structures: Hobbes and Coase meet repeated games. In Cook, K. (Ed.), Trust in society. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Gintis, H., Bowles, S., Boyd, R., & Fehr, E. (2005). Moral sentiments and material interests: Origins, evidence, and consequences. In Gintis, H., Bowles, S., Boyd, R., & Fehr, E. (Eds.), Moral sentiments and material interests: The foundation of cooperation in economic life. Cambridge: MIT.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, G. (1992). Managerial dilemmas: The political economy of hierarchy. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Huyck, J., Battalio, R., & Walters, M. (1995). Commitment versus discretion in the peasant-dictator game. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 143170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Huyck, J., Battalio, R., & Walters, M. (2001). Is reputation a substitute for commitment in the peasant- dictator game? Working Paper, Texas A&M University.Google Scholar
Weingast, B. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11, 131.Google Scholar
Weingast, B. (1997). The political foundations of democracy and the rule of law. American Political Science Review, 91, 245263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, B. (2005). The constitutional dilemma of economic liberty. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19, 89108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Appendix: Instructions (Ex Post Communication Treatment)

Cason and Mui supplementary material
Download Appendix: Instructions (Ex Post Communication Treatment)(File)
File 64.6 KB