Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-dlb68 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T18:14:44.409Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The breakdown of cooperation in iterative real-time trust dilemmas

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Ryan O. Murphy*
Affiliation:
Columbia University, Center for the Decision Sciences, 420 West 118th Street, Room 805A Mail Code 3355, New York, NY 10027
Amnon Rapoport*
Affiliation:
University of Arizona, Dept. of Management and Policy, 405 McClelland Hall, Tucson, AZ 85721 and Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Dept. of Economics, Kowloon, Hong Kong
James E. Parco*
Affiliation:
United States Air Force Academy, Dept. of Management, Colorado Springs, CO 80840

Abstract

We study a class of trust-based cooperation dilemmas that evolve in continuous time. Characteristic of these dilemmas is that as long as all n players continue to cooperate, their payoffs increase monotonically over time. Simultaneously, the temptation to defect increases too, as the first player to defect terminates the interaction and receives the present value of the payoff function whereas each of the other n — 1 players only receives a proportion δ (0 < δ < 1) of the defecting player's payoff. We introduce a novel experimental institution that we call the Real-Time Trust Game (RTTG) to examine this class of interactions. We then report the results from an iterated RTTG in which the values of n and δ are varied in a between-subjects design. In all conditions, cooperation breaks down in the population over iterations of the game. The rate of breakdown sharply increases as n increases and more slowly decreases as δ increases.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2006 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

The thoughts and opinions expressed in this manuscript are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the U.S. Government, the Department of Defense, or the United States Air Force.

References

Arrow, K. (1974). The Limits of Organizations. NY: Norton.Google Scholar
Aumann, R. J. (1992). Irrationality in game theory. In Dasgupta, P., Gale, D., Hart, O., and Maskin, E. (eds.), Economic Analysis of Markets and Games: Essays in Honor of Frank Hahn. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 214227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, R. J. (1995). Backward induction and common knowledge of rationality. Games and Economic Behavior, 8, 619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, R. J. (1998). On the centipede game. Games and Economic Behavior, 23, 97105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bacharach, M., Guerra, G., & Zizzo, D. J. (2001). Is trust self-fulfilling? An experimental study. Oxford University, Department of Economics, unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Ben-Porath, E. (1997). Rationality, Nash equilibrium and backwards induction in perfect-information games. Review of Economic Studies, 64, 2346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. A. (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 122142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonacich, P., Shure, G., Kahan, J., & Meeker, R., (1976). Cooperation and Group Size in the n-Person Prisoners’ Dilemma. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 20, 4, 687706.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burnham, T., McCabe, K.A., & Smith, V. L. (2000). Friend-or-foe intentionality priming in an extensive form trust game. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 43, 5773.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F. (2003). Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction. NY: Russell sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F. & Weigelt, H. K. (1988). Experimental tests of a sequential equilibrium reputation model. Econometrica, 56, 136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J.C. (2002). Trust, reciprocity, and other-regarding preferences: Groups vs. individuals and males vs. females. In Zwick, R. & Rapoport, A. (eds.), Experimental Business Research. NY: Kluwer, pp. 331349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engle-Warnick, J., & Slonim, R. L. (2001). The fragility and robustness of trust. Case Western Reserve University, Department of Economics, unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Fey, M., McKelvey, R. D., & Palfrey, T. R. (1996). An experimental study of constant-sum centipede games. International Journal of Game Theory, 25, 269287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fukuyama, F. (1995). Trust: The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. NY: Free Press.Google Scholar
Glaeser, E. L., Laibson, D. L., Scheinkman, J. A., & Soutter, C. L. (2000). Measuring trust. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125, 811846.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goren, H., Kurzban, R., & Rapoport, A. (2003). Social loafing vs. social enhancement: Public goods provisioning in real-time with irrevocable commitments. Organizational Behaviorand Human Decision Processes, 90, 277290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goren, H., Rapoport, A., & Kurzban, R. (2004). Revocable commitments to public goods provision under the real-time protocol of play. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 17, 1737.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guth, W., & Kliemt, H. (1994). Competition or co-operation-on the evolutionary economics of trust, exploitation and moral attitudes. Metroeconomica, 45, 155187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guth, W., Ockenfels, A., & Wendel, M. (1993). Efficiency by trust or fairness? Multiperiod ultimatum bargaining experiments with an increasing cake. International Journal of Game Theory, 22, 5173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guth, W., Ockenfels, A., & Wendel, M. (1997). Cooperation based on trust: An experimental investigation. Journal of Economic Psychology, 18, 1543.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ho, T. H., & Weigelt, K. (2001). Trust building among strangers. University of Pennsylvania, unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Ishii, K., & Kurzban, R. O. (2005). Real time pubic good games in Japan: Cultural and individual differences in trust and reciprocity. University of Pennsylvania, Dept. of Psychology, unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
James, H. S. (2002). The trust paradox: A survey of economic inquiries into the nature of trust and trustworthiness. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 47, 291307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahan, J. P., & Rapoport, A. (1974). Decisions of timing in bipolarized conflict situations with complete information. Acta Psychologica, 38, 183203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kramer, R. M. (2001). Trust rules for trust dilemmas: How decision makers think and act in the shadow of doubt. In Falcone, R., Singh, M., & Tan, Y. H. (eds.), Trust in Cyber-Societies. Berlin: Springer-Verlag, pp. 926.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurzban, R., McCabe, K. A., Smith, V. L., & Wilson, B. (2001). Incremental Commitment and Reciprocity in a Real-Time Public Goods Game. Personality & Social Psychology Bulletin, 27, 12, 16621673.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maskin, (eds.), Economic Analysis of Markets & Games: Essays in Honor of Frank Hahn. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 214227.Google Scholar
McCabe, K. A., Rassenti, S. J., & Smith, V. L. (1996). Game theory and reciprocity in some extensive form experimental games. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 93, 1342113428.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McCabe, K. A., Rassenti, S. J., & Smith, V. L. (1998). Reciprocity, trust, and payoff privacy in extensive form bargaining. Games and Economic Behavior, 24, 1024.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCabe, K. A., Rigdon, M., & Smith, V. L. (2002). Cooperation in single play, two-person extensive form games between anonymously matched players. In Zwick, R. & Rapoport, A. (eds.), Experimental Business Research. NY: Kluwer, pp. 5167.Google Scholar
McCabe, K. A., Smith, V. L., & LePore, M. (2000). Intentionality detection and “mindreading:” Why does game form matter? Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 97, 44044409.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McKelvey, R., & Palfrey, T. (1992). An experimental study of the centipede game. Econometrica, 60, 803836.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nagel, R., & Tang, F. F. (1998). Experimental results on the centipede game in normal form: An investigation of learning. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 42, 356384.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ortmann, A., Fitzgerald, J., & Boeing, C. (2000). Trust, reciprocity, and social history: A re-examination. Experimental Economics, 3, 81100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ponti, G. (2000). Cycles of learning in the centipede game. Games and Economic Behavior, 30, 115141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rapoport, A. (2003). Centipede games. In L. Nadel (ed.), Encyclopedia of Cognitive Science, Vol. 2. London: Macmillan, pp. 196203.Google Scholar
Rapoport, A., Stein, W. E., Parco, J. E., & Nicholas, T. E. (2003). Equilibrium play and adaptive learning in a three-person centipede game. Games and Economic Behavior, 43, 239265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reny, P. J. (1993). Common belief & the theory of games with perfect information. Journal of Economic Theory, 59, 257274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenthal, R. W. (1981). Games of perfect information, predatory pricing and the chain-store paradox. Journal of Economic Theory, 25, 92100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rousseau, D., Sitkin, S., Burt, R., & Camerer, C. (1998). Not so different after all: A Cross-Discipline View of Trust, Academy of Management Review, 23, 3, 393404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubinstein, A. (1982). Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica, 50, 97109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stalnaker, R. (1996). Knowledge, belief, and counterfactual reasoning in games. Economics and Philosophy, 12, 133163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stalnaker, R. (1998). Belief revision in games: Forward and backward induction. Mathematical Social Sciences, 36, 3156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, R., Camerer, C., Rottenstreich, Y., & Knez, M. (2001). The Illusion of Leadership: Misattribution of Cause in Coordination Games. Organization Science, 12,5, 582598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Murphy et al. supplementary material

Appendices 1 and 2
Download Murphy et al. supplementary material(File)
File 157.5 KB