Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-g9frx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T09:04:49.989Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Balancing the current account: experimental evidence on underconsumption

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Marcus Giamattei*
Affiliation:
University of Passau, Innstrasse 27, 94032 Passau, Germany
Johann Graf Lambsdorff*
Affiliation:
University of Passau, Innstrasse 27, 94032 Passau, Germany

Abstract

How should countries in a fixed exchange rate system balance their current account? This question was at the center of the historical debate between Keynes and White in 1944 and is being debated increasingly these days for the Eurozone. Should consolidation by deficit countries be complemented by higher spending in surplus countries in order to avoid a downward bias in the level of consumption? We investigate the associated disequilibrium behavior experimentally, letting our experimental subjects act as heads of state who repeatedly seek to coordinate their policies. If only deficits are punished, as proposed by White, we observe that consumption is persistently reduced and adjustment is slower than in a treatment in which a surplus is also punished, as suggested by Keynes. We find support for the fact that underconsumption occurs for behavioral but not for rational reasons.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2014 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-014-9422-z) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Amano, R, Kryvtsov, O, & Petersen, L (2014). Recent developments in experimental macroeconomics. Bank of Canada Review Autumn, 2014, 111.Google Scholar
Angeletos, G.-M., Lorenzoni, G., & Pavan, A. (2010). Beauty contests and irrational exuberance: A neoclassical approach. NBER Working Paper No. 15883.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Attanasio, O Taylor, JB, & Woodford, M (1999). Consumption. Handbook of macroeconomics, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science 741812. 10.1016/S1574-0048(99)10019-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bibow, J (2009). Keynes on monetary policy, finance and uncertainty: Liquidity preference theory and the global financial crisis, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O., & Milesi-Ferretti, G. M. (2009). Global imbalances: In midstream? IMF Staff Position Note SPN/09/29. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Boughton, J. (2002). Why White, not Keynes? Inventing the postwar international monetary system. IMF Working Paper 02/52. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Caliari, A. (2011). Adapting the international monetary system to face 21st century challenges. DESA Working Paper No. 104. New York: United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs.Google Scholar
Camerer, CF (2003). Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cameron, AC, Gelbach, JB, & Miller, DL (2011). Robust inference with multiway clustering. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 29(2), 238249 1217.62087 2807878 10.1198/jbes.2010.07136CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J, & Deaton, A (1989). Why is consumption so smooth?. Review of Economic Studies, 56(3), 357374. 10.2307/2297552CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J, & Mankiw, NG (1990). Permanent income, current income, and consumption. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 8(3), 265279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carney, M. (2009, 19 November). The evolution of the international monetary system. New York: Foreign Policy Association. Accessed October 29, 2013, from http://www.bankofcanada.ca/wp-content/uploads/2010/03/sp191109.pdf.Google Scholar
Carroll, CJ, Slacalek, , & Sommer, M (2011). International evidence on sticky consumption growth. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 93(4), 11351145. 10.1162/REST_a_00122CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cartapanis, A, & Herland, M (2002). The reconstruction of the international financial architecture: Keynes’ revenge?. Review of International Political Economy, 9(2), 271297. 10.1080/09692290110126119CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clausen, J. R., & Kandil, M. (2005). On cyclicality in the current and financial accounts: Evidence from nine industrial countries. IMF Working Paper 05/56. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Cornand, C, & Heinemann, F (2013). Measuring agents’ reaction to private and public information in games with strategic complementarities. Experimental Economics, 17(1), 6177. 10.1007/s10683-013-9357-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cornand, C, Heinemann, F Isaac, RM, Norton, D, & Duffy, J (2014). Experiments on monetary policy and central banking. Experiments in macroeconomics (Research in experimental economics, Volume 17), Bingley: Emerald Group Publishing Limited 167227.Google Scholar
Crawford, V, Costa-Gomes, M, & Iriberri, N (2013). Structural models of nonequilibrium strategic thinking: Theory, evidence, and application. Journal of Economic Literature, 53(1), 562. 10.1257/jel.51.1.5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Grauwe, P. (2013). Design failures in the Eurozone: Can they be fixed?. LSE Europe in Question Discussion Paper Series 5. London: London, School of Economics and Political Science.Google Scholar
Deaton, A (1992). Understanding consumption, Oxford: Clarendon Press 10.1093/0198288247.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffy, J. (2012). Macroeconomics: A survey of laboratory research. In Kagel, J. & Roth, A. (Eds.), The handbook of experimental economics (2nd ed.). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Accessed December 3, 2013, from http://www.pitt.edu/~jduffy/papers/heeAug12.pdf.Google Scholar
Duffy, J, & Nagel, R (1997). On the robustness of behaviour in experimental beauty contest games. The Economic Journal, 107(445), 16841700. 10.1111/j.1468-0297.1997.tb00075.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, B. (2009). Out of the box. Thoughts about the international financial architecture. IMF Working Paper 09/116. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Commission, European. (2012). Current account surpluses in the EU. The European Economy Series 9/2012. Accessed November 19, 2013, from http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/european_economy/2012/pdf/ee-2012-9_en.pdf.Google Scholar
Commission, European. (2013). Report from The Commission to The European Parliament, The Council, The European Central Bank and The European Economic And Social Committee. Alert Mechanism Report 2014. Accessed November 20, 2013, from http://ec.europa.eu/europe2020/pdf/2014/amr2014_en.pdf.Google Scholar
Feldstein, M. (2012, January/February). The failure of the Euro. Foreign Affairs.Google Scholar
Fischbacher, U (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fuhrer, J (2000). Habit formation in consumption and its implications for monetary-policy models. American Economic Review, 90(3), 367390. 10.1257/aer.90.3.367CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galí, J, López-Salido, JD, & Vallés, J (2007). Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption. Journal of the European Economic Association, 5(1), 227270. 10.1162/JEEA.2007.5.1.227CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, M. (2010). Confronting asset bubbles, too big to fail, and beggar-thy-neighbor exchange rate policies. Policy Briefs in International Economics 10-3. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Greenwald, B, Stiglitz, JE et al., Griffith-Jones, S et al., (2009). A modest proposal for international monetary reform. Time for a visible hand—Lessons from the 2008 world financial crisis, Oxford: Oxford University Press 314344.Google Scholar
Güth, W, Kocher, M, & Sutter, M (2002). Experimental ‘beauty contest’ with homogeneous and heterogeneous players and with interior and boundary equilibria. Economic Letters, 74(2), 219228 1002.91011 10.1016/S0165-1765(01)00544-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haltiwanger, J, & Waldman, M (1989). Limited rationality and strategic complements: The implications for macroeconomics. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(3), 463483. 10.2307/2937806CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ho, T-H, Camerer, C, & Weigelt, K (1998). Iterated dominance and iterated best response in experimental “p-beauty contests”. American Economic Review, 88(4), 947969.Google Scholar
Hoover, KD Harcourt, GC, & Riach, PA (1997). Is there a place for rational expectations in Keynes’ general theory?. A “second edition” of the general theory, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Fund, International Monetary. (2010). Reserve accumulation and international monetary stability. Accessed October 29, 2013, from http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2010/041310.pdf.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1942). Proposals for an International Currency (or Clearing) Union. (Reprinted in The International Monetary Fund 1945–1965. 20 Years of International Monetary Cooperation. Volume III: Documents, pp. 318, by J. K. Horsefield, Ed., 1969, Washington: International Monetary Fund).Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1943). Proposal for an International Clearing Union. (Reprinted in The International Monetary Fund 1945–1965. 20 Years of International Monetary Cooperation. Volume III: Documents, pp. 1936, by J. K. Horsefield, Ed., 1969. Washington: International Monetary Fund).Google Scholar
Lambsdorff, J Graf, Schubert, M, & Giamattei, M (2013). On the role of heuristics—Experimental evidence on inflation dynamics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 37(6), 12131229 3041955 10.1016/j.jedc.2013.02.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mateos y Lago, I., Duttagupta, R., & Goyal, R. (2009). The debate on the International Monetary System. IMF Staff Position Note 09/26. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Mattoo, A, & Subramanian, A (2009). Currency undervaluation and sovereign wealth funds: A new role for the World Trade Organization. The World Economy, 32(8), 11351164. 10.1111/j.1467-9701.2009.01199.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R, & Palfrey, T (1995). Quantal response equilibria for normal form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1), 638 0832.90126 1347932 10.1006/game.1995.1023CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R, & Palfrey, T (1998). Quantal Response equilibria for extensive form games. Experimental Economics, 1(1), 941 0920.90141 10.1023/A:1009905800005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morris, St, & Shin, H (2002). The social value of public information. American Economic Review, 92(5), 15211534. 10.1257/000282802762024610CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nagel, R (1995). Unraveling in guessing games: An experimental study. American Economic Review, 85(5), 13131326.Google Scholar
Piffaretti, N (2009). Reshaping the international monetary architecture: Lessons from the Keynes Plan. Banks and Bank Systems, 4(1), 4554.Google Scholar
Seckin, A (2001). Consumption–leisure choice with habit formation. Economics Letters, 70(1), 115120 0968.91008 10.1016/S0165-1765(00)00330-XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spahn, H-P et al., Hirai, T et al., (2013). In a Keynesian mood? Why exchange rate systems collapse. Keynesian reflections, Oxford: Oxford University Press 196222.Google Scholar
Stahl, D, & Wilson, P (1995). On players models of other players: Theory and experimental evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1), 218254 0831.90135 1347938 10.1006/game.1995.1031CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steil, B (2013). The battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White, and the making of a new world order, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press 10.1515/9781400846573CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, J (2011). Rethinking macroeconomics: What failed, and how to repair it. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(4), 591645. 10.1111/j.1542-4774.2011.01030.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, J, & Greenwald, B (2010). Towards a new global reserve system. Journal of Globalization and Development, 1(2), 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sutan, A, & Willinger, M (2009). Guessing with negative feedback: An experiment. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 33(5), 11231133 1170.91346 2512249 10.1016/j.jedc.2009.01.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nations, United. (2009). Report of the Commission of Experts of the President of the UN General Assembly on Reforms of the International Monetary and Financial System. New York. Accessed October 2, 2014, from http://www.un.org/ga/econcrisissummit/docs/FinalReport_CoE.pdf.Google Scholar
Williamson, J. (2011). Getting surplus countries to adjust. Policy Brief in International Economics 11-01. Accessed May 30, 2013, from http://www.iie.com/publications/pb/pb11-01.pdf.Google Scholar
Woodford, M (2003). Interest and prices. Foundations of a theory of monetary policy, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Giamattei and Lambsdorff supplementary material

Appendix 3
Download Giamattei and Lambsdorff supplementary material(File)
File 620 KB