Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-9klzr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T09:04:48.912Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A survey of experimental research on contests, all-pay auctions and tournaments

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Emmanuel Dechenaux
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Kent State University, Kent, OH 44242, USA
Dan Kovenock
Affiliation:
Economic Science Institute, Chapman University, One University Drive, 92866 Orange, CA, USA
Roman M. Sheremeta*
Affiliation:
Economic Science Institute, Chapman University, One University Drive, 92866 Orange, CA, USA Weatherhead School of Management, Case Western Reserve University, 11119 Bellflower Road, 44106 Cleveland, OH, USA

Abstract

Many economic, political and social environments can be described as contests in which agents exert costly effort while competing over the distribution of a scarce resource. These environments have been studied using Tullock contests, all-pay auctions and rank-order tournaments. This survey provides a comprehensive review of experimental research on these three canonical contests. First, we review studies investigating the basic structure of contests, including the number of players and prizes, spillovers and externalities, heterogeneity, risk and incomplete information. Second, we discuss dynamic contests and multi-battle contests. Then we review studies examining sabotage, feedback, bias, collusion, alliances, group contests and gender, as well as field experiments. Finally, we discuss applications of contests and suggest directions for future research.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2014 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abbink, K, Brandts, J, Herrmann, B, & Orzen, H (2010). Inter-group conflict and intra-group punishment in an experimental contest game. American Economic Review, 100, 420447. 10.1257/aer.100.1.420CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abbink, K, Brandts, J, Herrmann, B, & Orzen, H (2012). Parochial altruism in inter-group conflicts. Economics Letters, 117, 4548. 10.1016/j.econlet.2012.04.083CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Agranov, M, & Tergiman, C (2013). Incentives and compensation schemes: An experimental study. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 31, 238247. 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2012.06.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahn, TK, Isaac, RM, & Salmon, TC (2011). Rent seeking in groups. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 29, 116125. 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2010.01.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Altmann, S, Falk, A, & Wibral, M (2012). Promotions and incentives: The case of multistage elimination tournaments. Journal of Labor Economics, 30, 149174. 10.1086/662130CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amaldoss, W, Meyer, RJ, Raju, JS, & Rapoport, A (2000). Collaborating to compete. Marketing Science, 19, 105126. 10.1287/mksc.19.2.105.11804CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amaldoss, W, Rapoport, A, & Columbus, F (2009). Excessive expenditure in two-stage contests: Theory and experimental evidence. Game theory: Strategies, equilibria, and theorems, Hauppauge, NY: Nova Science Publishers.Google Scholar
Amegashie, JA, Cadsby, CB, & Song, Y (2007). Competitive burnout: Theory and experimental evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 59, 213239 1162.91353 2330338 10.1016/j.geb.2006.08.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, LA, & Freeborn, BA (2010). Varying the intensity of competition in a multiple prize rent seeking experiment. Public Choice, 143, 237254. 10.1007/s11127-009-9482-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, LA, & Stafford, SL (2003). An experimental analysis of rent seeking under varying competitive conditions. Public Choice, 115, 199216. 10.1023/A:1022817613815CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arad, A (2012). The tennis coach problem: A game-theoretic and experimental study. The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, 12, 10 2923234 10.1515/1935-1704.1738CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arad, A, & Rubinstein, A (2012). Multi-dimensional iterative reasoning in action: The case of the Colonel Blotto game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 84, 571585. 10.1016/j.jebo.2012.09.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Avrahami, J, & Kareev, Y (2009). Do the weak stand a chance? Distribution of resources in a competitive environment. Cognitive Science, 33, 940950 21585491 10.1111/j.1551-6709.2009.01039.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baik, KH (1993). Effort levels in contests: The public-good prize case. Economics Letters, 41, 363367 0782.90024 10.1016/0165-1765(93)90206-RCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baik, KH (1994). Effort levels in contests with two asymmetric players. Southern Economic Journal, 61, 367378. 10.2307/1059984CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baik, KH, Cherry, TL, Kroll, S, & Shogren, JF (1999). Endogenous timing in a gaming tournament. Theory and Decision, 47, 121 0948.91003 10.1023/A:1005033020124CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baik, KH, & Shogren, JF (1992). Strategic behavior in contests: Comment. American Economic Review, 82, 359362.Google Scholar
Balafoutas, L, Kerschbamer, R, & Sutter, M (2012). Distributional preferences and competitive behavior. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 83, 125135. 10.1016/j.jebo.2011.06.018CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Balafoutas, L, & Sutter, M (2012). Affirmative action policies promote women and do not harm efficiency in the lab. Science, 335, 579582 1:CAS:528:DC%2BC38XhsVequrs%3D 22301317 2012Sci...335..579B 10.1126/science.1211180CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bandiera, O, Barankay, I, & Rasul, I (2005). Social preferences and the response to incentives: Evidence from personnel data. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 917962.Google Scholar
Bandiera, O, Barankay, I, & Rasul, I (2006). The evolution of cooperative norms: Evidence from a natural field experiment. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 6, 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bandiera, O, Barankay, I, & Rasul, I (2013). Team incentives: evidence from a firm level experiment. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11, 10791114. 10.1111/jeea.12028CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barankay, I. (2011). Rankings and social tournaments: evidence from a crowd-sourcing experiment. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Bartling, B, Fehr, E, Marechal, MA, & Schunk, D (2009). Egalitarianism and competitiveness. American Economic Review, 99, 9398. 10.1257/aer.99.2.93CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barut, Y, & Kovenock, D (1998). The symmetric multiple prize all-pay auction with complete information. European Journal of Political Economy, 14, 627644. 10.1016/S0176-2680(98)00029-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barut, Y, Kovenock, D, & Noussair, CN (2002). A comparison of multiple-unit all-pay and winner-pay auctions under incomplete information. International Economic Review, 43, 675708. 10.1111/1468-2354.t01-1-00031CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baye, MR, & Hoppe, HC (2003). The strategic equivalence of rent-seeking, innovation, and patent-race games. Games and Economic Behavior, 44, 217226 1056.91015 1995664 10.1016/S0899-8256(03)00027-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baye, MR, Kovenock, D, & de Vries, CG (1993). Rigging the lobbying process: An application of the all-pay auction. American Economic Review, 83, 289294.Google Scholar
Baye, MR, Kovenock, D, & de Vries, CG (1994). The solution to the Tullock rent-seeking game when r is greater than 2: Mixed-strategy equilibria and mean dissipation rates. Public Choice, 81, 363380. 10.1007/BF01053238CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baye, MR, Kovenock, D, & de Vries, CG (1996). The all-pay auction with complete information. Economic Theory, 8, 291305 0859.90058 1403229 10.1007/BF01211819CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baye, MR, Kovenock, D, & de Vries, CG (2005). Comparative analysis of litigation systems: an auction-theoretic approach. Economic Journal, 115, 583601. 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2005.01010.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baye, MR, Kovenock, D, & de Vries, CG (2012). Contests with rank-order spillovers. Economic Theory, 51, 350351. 10.1007/s00199-009-0489-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bigoni, M., Fort, M., Nardotto, M., & Reggiani, T. (2011). Teams or tournaments? A field experiment on cooperation and competition in academic achievement. Working Paper, Università di Bologna.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilodeau, M, Childs, J, & Mestelman, S (2004). Volunteering a public service: An experimental investigation. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 28392855. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2004.02.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blimpo, M. P. (2014). Team incentives for education in developing countries: A randomized field experiment in Benin. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 6, 90109.Google Scholar
Bloch, F Garfinkel, Michelle R, & Skaperdas, Stergios (2012). Endogenous formation of alliances in conflicts. Oxford handbook of the economics of peace and conflict, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Bolle, F, Tan, JHW, & Zizzo, DJ (2014). Vendettas. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 6, 93130.Google Scholar
Borel, E. (1921). La théorie du jeu les équations intégrales a noyau symétrique. Comptes Rendus de l’Académie, 173, 13041308; English translation by Savage, L. (1953). The theory of play and integral equations with skew symmetric kernels. Econometrica, 21, 97100.Google Scholar
Brookins, P, & Ryvkin, D (2014). An experimental study of bidding in contests of incomplete information. Experimental Economics, 17, 245261. 10.1007/s10683-013-9365-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bull, C, Schotter, A, & Weigelt, K (1987). Tournaments and piece rates: An experimental study. Journal of Political Economy, 95, 133. 10.1086/261439CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bullock, D, & Rutström, E (2007). Policy making and rent-dissipation: An experimental test. Experimental Economics, 10, 2136 1161.91486 10.1007/s10683-006-9133-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caldara, M. (2012). Bidding behavior in pay-to-bid auctions: An experimental study. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Calsamiglia, C, Franke, J, & Rey-Biel, P (2013). The incentive effects of affirmative action in a real-effort tournament. Journal of Public Economics, 98, 1531. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2012.11.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, J, Holmes, J, & Matthews, P (2008). Charity auctions: A field experiment. Economic Journal, 118, 92113. 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02105.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, J, Matthews, P, & Schirm, J (2010). Tournaments and office politics: Evidence from a real effort experiment. American Economic Review, 100, 504517. 10.1257/aer.100.1.504CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casas-Arce, P, & Martinez-Jerez, FA (2009). Relative performance compensation, contests, and dynamic incentives. Management Science, 55, 13061320 1232.91403 10.1287/mnsc.1090.1021CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, TN, Masters, WA, & Sheremeta, RM (2010). Entry into winner-take-all and proportional-prize contests: An experimental study. Journal of Public Economics, 94, 604611. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2010.05.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, T. N., Masters, W. A., & Sheremeta, R. M. (2013). Winner-take-all and proportional-prize contests: theory and experimental results. Economic Science Institute, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Cason, TN, Sheremeta, RM, & Zhang, J (2012). Communication and efficiency in competitive coordination games. Games and Economic Behavior, 76, 2643 1274.91024 2955979 10.1016/j.geb.2012.05.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, TN, Sheremeta, RM, & Zhang, J (2014). Asymmetric and endogenous communication in competition between groups. Games and Economic Behavior, 76, 2643 2955979 10.1016/j.geb.2012.05.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chark, R, Rapoport, A, & Zwick, R (2011). Experimental comparison of two multiple-stage contest designs with asymmetric players. Public Choice, 147, 305329. 10.1007/s11127-010-9631-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, Kuhn, P Ashenfelter, O, & Card, D (2011). Lab labor: What can labor economists learn from the lab?. Handbook of labor economics, Amsterdam: Elsevier 229331.Google Scholar
Chen, H, Ham, SH, & Lim, N (2011). Designing multiperson tournaments with asymmetric contestants: An experimental study. Management Science, 57, 864883 1217.91031 10.1287/mnsc.1110.1325CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cherry, TL, & Cotten, SJ (2011). Sleeping with the enemy: The economic cost of internal environmental conflicts. Economic Inquiry, 49, 530539. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2010.00329.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chowdhury, SM, Kovenock, D, & Sheremeta, RM (2013). An experimental investigation of Colonel Blotto games. Economic Theory, 52, 833861 1268.91049 3049354 10.1007/s00199-011-0670-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chowdhury, SM, & Sheremeta, RM (2011). A generalized Tullock contest. Public Choice, 147, 413420. 10.1007/s11127-010-9636-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chowdhury, SM, & Sheremeta, RM (2011). Multiple equilibria in Tullock contests. Economics Letters, 112, 216219 1218.91005 2857560 10.1016/j.econlet.2011.05.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chowdhury, S. M., & Sheremeta, R. M. (2014). Strategically equivalent contests. Theory and Decision. doi:10.1007/s11238-014-9440-5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chowdhury, SM, Sheremeta, RM, & Lee, D (2013). Top guns may not fire: Best-shot group contests with group-specific public good prizes. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 92, 94103. 10.1016/j.jebo.2013.04.012CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chowdhury, SM, Sheremeta, RM, & Turocy, TL (2014). Overbidding and overspreading in rent-seeking experiments: Cost structure and prize allocation rules. Games and Economic Behavior., 87, 224238 1302.91051 3257421 10.1016/j.geb.2014.05.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chung, TY (1996). Rent-seeking contest when the prize increases with aggregate efforts. Public Choice, 87, 5566. 10.1007/BF00151729CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cinar, Y, & Goksel, T (2012). An experimental analysis of Colonel Blotto games under alternative environments. İktisat İşletme ve Finans, 27, 3957. 10.3848/iif.2012.312.3271CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, DJ, & Konrad, KA (2007). Asymmetric conflict: Weakest link against best shot. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 51, 457469. 10.1177/0022002707300320CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, DJ, & Riis, C (1998). Influence and the discretionary allocation of several prizes. European Journal of Political Economy, 14, 605625. 10.1016/S0176-2680(98)00028-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, C, & Shavit, T (2012). Experimental tests of Tullock’s contest with and without winner refunds. Research in Economics, 66, 263272. 10.1016/j.rie.2012.04.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corazzini, L, Faravelli, M, & Stanca, L (2010). A prize to give for: An experiment on public good funding mechanisms. Economic Journal, 120, 944967. 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2009.02314.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cornes, R, & Hartley, R (2012). Risk aversion in symmetric and asymmetric contests. Economic Theory, 51, 247275 1263.91005 2983352 10.1007/s00199-009-0490-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coughlan, P. J., & Plott, C. (1997) An experimental analysis of the structure of legal fees: American rule vs. English rule. California Institute of Technology, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Croson, R, & Gneezy, U (2009). Gender differences in preferences. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 448474. 10.1257/jel.47.2.448CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dasgupta, P Stiglitz, JE, & Mathewson, GF (1986). The theory of technological competition. New developments in the analysis of market structure, Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Davis, D, Razzolini, L, Reilly, R, Wilson, BJ Davis, DD, & Isaac, M (2006). Raising revenues for charity: Auctions versus lotteries. Research in Experimental Economics, Greenwich: JAI Press.Google Scholar
Davis, D, & Reilly, R (1998). Do many cooks always spoil the stew? An experimental analysis of rent seeking and the role of a strategic buyer. Public Choice, 95, 89115. 10.1023/A:1004916624881CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Paola, M, Scoppa, V, & Nisticò, R (2012). Monetary incentives and student achievement in a depressed labor market: Results from a randomized experiment. Journal of Human Capital, 6, 5685. 10.1086/664795CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dechenaux, E., Kovenock, D., & Sheremeta, R. M. (2012). A survey of experimental research on contests, all-pay auctions and tournaments. Economic Science Institute, Working paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dechenaux, E, & Mancini, M (2008). Auction-theoretic approach to modeling legal systems: An experimental analysis. Applied Economics Research Bulletin, 2, 142177.Google Scholar
Deck, C, & Farmer, A (2009). Strategic bidding and investments in final offer arbitration: Theory and experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 70, 361373. 10.1016/j.jebo.2009.01.010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deck, C., Foster, J., & Song, H. (2012). Alliances in defense against an opportunistic opponent: Theory and experiments. Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deck, C. & Jahedi, S. (2014). Time discounting in strategic contests. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Deck, C, & Sheremeta, RM (2012). Fight or flight? Defending against sequential attacks in the game of siege. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 56, 10691088. 10.1177/0022002712438355CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delfgaauw, J, Dur, R, Sol, J, & Verbeke, W (2013). Tournament incentives in the field: Gender differences in the workplace. Journal of Labor Economics, 31, 305326. 10.1086/667996CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delfgaauw, J., Dur, R., Sol, J. & Verbeke, W. (2014). The effects of prize spread and noise in elimination tournaments: A natural field experiment. Journal of Labor Economics, forthcoming.Google Scholar
DeScioli, P, & Wilson, BJ (2011). The territorial foundations of human property. Evolution and Human Behavior, 32, 297304. 10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2010.10.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dickinson, DL (2001). The carrot vs. the stick in work team motivation. Experimental Economics, 4, 107124 1012.91506 10.1023/A:1011449606931CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dickinson, DL, & Isaac, MR (1998). Absolute and relative rewards for individuals in team production. Managerial and Decision Economics, 19, 299310. 10.1002/(SICI)1099-1468(199806/08)19:4/5<299::AID-MDE892>3.0.CO;2-T3.0.CO;2-T>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diekmann, A (1985). Volunteer’s dilemma. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 29, 605610. 10.1177/0022002785029004003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diekmann, A Diekmann, A, & Mitter, P (1986). Volunteer’s dilemma: A social trap without a dominant strategy and some empirical results. Paradoxical effects of social behavior: Essays in honor of anatol rapoport, Heidelberg: Physica-Verlag 187197. 10.1007/978-3-642-95874-8_13CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diekmann, A (1993). Cooperation in asymmetric volunteer’s dilemma game: Theory and experimental evidence. International Journal of Game Theory, 22, 7585 0775.90303 1229866 10.1007/BF01245571CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, AK (1987). Strategic behavior in contests. American Economic Review, 77, 891898.Google Scholar
Dohmen, T, & Falk, A (2011). Performance pay and multidimensional sorting: Productivity, preferences, and gender. American Economic Review, 101, 556590. 10.1257/aer.101.2.556CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drago, R, & Heywood, JS (1989). Tournaments, piece rates, and the shape of the payoff function. Journal of Political Economy, 97, 992998. 10.1086/261639CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffy, J, & Kornienko, T (2010). Does competition affect giving?. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 74, 82103. 10.1016/j.jebo.2010.02.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Durham, Y, Hirshleifer, J, & Smith, VL (1998). Do the rich get richer and the poor poorer? Experimental tests of a model of power. American Economic Review, 88, 970983.Google Scholar
Ederer, F (2010). Feedback and motivation in dynamic tournaments. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 19, 733769. 10.1111/j.1530-9134.2010.00268.xGoogle Scholar
Ederer, F. & Fehr, E. (2009). Deception and incentives: how dishonesty undermines effort provision. IZA, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Eisenkopf, G. & Teyssier, S. (2012). Horizontal and vertical social preferences in tournaments. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Eisenkopf, G, & Teyssier, S (2013). Envy and loss aversion in tournaments. Journal of Economic Psychology, 34, 240255. 10.1016/j.joep.2012.06.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erev, I, Bornstein, G, & Galili, R (1993). Constructive intergroup competition as a solution to the free rider problem: A field experiment. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 29, 463478. 10.1006/jesp.1993.1021CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ericsson, KA, & Charness, N (1994). Expert performance: Its structure and acquisition. American Psychologist, 49, 725747. 10.1037/0003-066X.49.8.725CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eriksson, T, Poulsen, A, & Villeval, MC (2009). Feedback and incentives: Experimental evidence. Labour Economics, 16, 679688. 10.1016/j.labeco.2009.08.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eriksson, T, Teyssier, S, & Villeval, MC (2009). Self-selection and the efficiency of tournaments. Economic Inquiry, 47, 530548. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2007.00094.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ernst, C, & Thöni, C (2013). Bimodal bidding in experimental all-pay auctions. Games, 4, 608623 3159007 10.3390/g4040608CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A., Fehr, E., & Huffman, D. (2008). The power and limits of tournament incentives. WZB, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Fallucchi, F, Renner, E, & Sefton, M (2013). Information feedback and contest structure in rent-seeking games. European Economic Review, 64, 223240. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2013.09.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, D., & Schmidt, J. (2011). Exclusion in the all-pay auction: An experimental investigation. WZB, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Fershtman, C, & Gneezy, U (2011). The trade-off between performance and quitting in high-power tournaments. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9, 318336. 10.1111/j.1542-4774.2010.01012.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Filippin, A, & Guala, F (2013). Costless discrimination and unequal achievements in an experimental tournament. Experimental economics, 16, 285305. 10.1007/s10683-012-9334-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fonseca, MA (2009). An experimental investigation of asymmetric contests. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 27, 582591. 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2009.01.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, RB, & Gelber, AM (2010). Prize structure and information in tournaments: Experimental evidence. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2, 149164.Google Scholar
Friedman, L (1958). Game-theory models in the allocation of advertising expenditure. Operations Research, 6, 699709 97985 10.1287/opre.6.5.699CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fu, Q, & Lu, J (2009). The beauty of “bigness”: on optimal design of multi winner contests. Games and Economic Behavior, 66, 146161 1161.91368 2527769 10.1016/j.geb.2008.05.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D, Gilbert, R, Stiglitz, J, & Tirole, J (1983). Preemption, leapfrogging and competition in patent races. European Economic Review, 22, 331. 10.1016/0014-2921(83)90087-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D, & Tirole, J (1986). A theory of exit in duopoly. Econometrica, 54, 943960 0596.90015 853991 10.2307/1912845CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fullerton, R, Linster, BG, McKee, M, & Slate, S (1999). An experimental investigation of research tournaments. Economic Inquiry, 37, 624636. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.1999.tb01452.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerchak, Y, & He, QM (2003). When will the range of prizes in tournaments increase in the noise or in the number of players?. International Game Theory Review, 5, 151166 1135.91004 1991686 10.1142/S0219198903000957CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gill, D, & Prowse, V (2012). A structural analysis of disappointment aversion in a real effort competition. American Economic Review, 102, 469503. 10.1257/aer.102.1.469CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, U, Niederle, M, & Rustichini, A (2003). Performance in competitive environments: Gender differences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 10491074 1072.91656 10.1162/00335530360698496CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, U, & Rustichini, A (2004). Gender and competition at a young age. American Economic Review, 94, 377381. 10.1257/0002828041301821CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, U, & Smorodinsky, R (2006). All-pay auctions—An experimental study. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 61, 255275. 10.1016/j.jebo.2004.09.013CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gradstein, M (1995). Intensity of competition, entry and entry deterrence in rent seeking contest. Economics and Politics, 7, 7991. 10.1111/j.1468-0343.1995.tb00105.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gradstein, M, & Konrad, KA (1999). Orchestrating rent seeking contests. Economic Journal, 109, 536545. 10.1111/1468-0297.00461CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grosskopf, B., Rentschler, L., & Sarin, R. (2010). Asymmetric information in contests: Theory and experiments. Texas A&M University, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Gunnthorsdottir, A, & Rapoport, A (2006). Embedding social dilemmas in intergroup competition reduces free-riding. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 101, 184199. 10.1016/j.obhdp.2005.08.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gürtler, O, & Harbring, C (2010). Feedback in tournaments under commitment problems: Experimental evidence. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 19, 771810. 10.1111/j.1530-9134.2010.00269.xGoogle Scholar
Gürtler, O, Münster, J, & Nieken, P (2013). Information policy in tournaments with sabotage. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 115, 932966. 10.1111/sjoe.12019CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harbring, C (2006). The effect of communication in incentive systems—An experimental study. Managerial and Decision Economics, 27, 333353. 10.1002/mde.1266CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harbring, C, & Irlenbusch, B (2003). An experimental study on tournament design. Labour Economics, 10, 443464. 10.1016/S0927-5371(03)00034-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harbring, C, & Irlenbusch, B (2005). Incentives in tournaments with endogenous prize selection. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 127, 636663. 10.1628/093245605775075951CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harbring, C, & Irlenbusch, B (2008). How many winners are good to have? On tournaments with sabotage. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 65, 682702. 10.1016/j.jebo.2006.03.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harbring, C, & Irlenbusch, B (2011). Sabotage in tournaments: Evidence from a laboratory experiment. Management Science, 57, 611627. 10.1287/mnsc.1100.1296CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harbring, C, Irlenbusch, B, Krakel, M, & Selten, R (2007). Sabotage in corporate contests—An experimental analysis. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 14, 367392. 10.1080/13571510701597445CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harbring, C, & Lünser, GK (2008). On the competition of asymmetric agents. German Economic Review, 9, 373395. 10.1111/j.1468-0475.2008.00438.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, C, & Vickers, J (1985). Perfect equilibrium in a model of a race. Review of Economic Studies, 52, 193209 0555.90031 789758 10.2307/2297616CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, C, & Vickers, J (1987). Racing with uncertainty. Review of Economic Studies, 54, 121 0602.90146 875799 10.2307/2297442CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrison, GW, & List, JA (2004). Field experiments. Journal of Economic Literature, 42, 10091055. 10.1257/0022051043004577CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, S (2008). Discrete colonel Blotto and general Lotto games. International Journal of Game Theory, 36, 441460 1151.91013 2383471 10.1007/s00182-007-0099-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Healy, A, & Pate, J (2010). Can teams help to close the gender competition gap?. Economic Journal, 155, 11921204.Google Scholar
Herbst, L., Konrad, K. A., & Morath, F. (2014). Endogenous group formation in experimental contests. Max Planck Institute for Tax Law and Public Finance, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Herrmann, B., & Orzen, H. (2008). The appearance of homo rivalis: Social preferences and the nature of rent seeking. University of Nottingham, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Hillman, A, & Riley, JG (1989). Politically contestable rents and transfers. Economics and Politics, 1, 1740. 10.1111/j.1468-0343.1989.tb00003.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, J., & Riley, J. G. (1978). Elements of the theory of auctions and contests. UCLA, Working Papers.Google Scholar
Holt, C. A., Kydd, A., Razzolini, L., & Sheremeta, R. M. (2014). The paradox of misaligned profiling: Theory and experimental evidence. Journal of Conflict Resolution, forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holt, CA, & Laury, SK (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92, 16441655. 10.1257/000282802762024700CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hörisch, H, & Kirchkamp, O (2010). Less fighting than expected—Experiments with wars of attrition and all-pay auctions. Public Choice, 144, 347367. 10.1007/s11127-009-9523-yCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hortala-Vallve, R, & Llorente-Saguer, A (2010). A simple mechanism for resolving conflict. Games and Economic Behavior, 70, 375391 1200.91070 2761668 10.1016/j.geb.2010.02.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hossain, T., Hong, F., & List, J. A. (2014). Framing manipulations in contests: A natural field experiment. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Irfanoglu, B., Mago, S. D., & Sheremeta, R. M. (2014). Sequential versus simultaneous election contests: An experimental study. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D, & Tversky, A (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263291 0411.90012 10.2307/1914185CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalra, A, & Shi, M (2001). Designing optimal sales contests: A theoretical perspective. Marketing Science, 20, 170193. 10.1287/mksc.20.2.170.10193CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katz, E, Nitzan, S, & Rosenberg, J (1990). Rent-seeking for pure public goods. Public Choice, 65, 4960. 10.1007/BF00139290CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ke, C. (2011). Fight alone or together? The need to belong. Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ke, C, Konrad, KA, & Morath, F (2013). Brothers in arms – An experiment on the alliance puzzle. Games and Economic Behavior, 77, 6176 1274.91120 2983443 10.1016/j.geb.2012.08.011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ke, C., Konrad, K. A., & Morath, F. (2014). Alliances in the shadow of conflict. Economic Inquiry, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Kimbrough, E., Rubin, J., Sheremeta, R., & Shields, T. (2013). Commitment problems in conflict resolution. Economic Science Institute, Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kimbrough, EO, & Sheremeta, RM (2013). Side-payments and the costs of conflict. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 31, 278286. 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2012.01.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kimbrough, EO, & Sheremeta, RM (2014). Why can’t we be friends? Entitlements and the costs of conflict. Journal of Peace Research, 51, 487500. 10.1177/0022343314524428CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kimbrough, EO, Sheremeta, RM, & Shields, T (2014). When parity promotes peace: Resolving conflict between asymmetric agents. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 99, 96108. 10.1016/j.jebo.2013.12.021CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klose, B., & Sheremeta, R.M. (2012). Behavior in all-pay and winner-pay auctions with identity-dependent externalities. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Klumpp, T, & Polborn, MK (2006). Primaries and the New Hampshire effect. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 10731114. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2005.08.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kohli, P., Bachrach, Y., Stillwell, D., Kearns, M., Herbrich, R., & Graepel, T. (2012). Colonel Blotto on facebook: The effect of social relations on strategic interaction. ACM Web Sciences 2012, ACM Conference on Web Sciences.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Konrad, KA (2009). Strategy and dynamics in contests, New York, NY: Oxford University Press 1182.91004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Konrad, KA, & Kovenock, D (2009). Multi-battle contests. Games and Economic Behavior, 66, 256274 1161.91318 2527775 10.1016/j.geb.2008.05.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kosfeld, M, & Neckermann, S (2011). Getting more work for nothing? Symbolic awards and worker performance. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 3, 8699.Google Scholar
Kovenock, D., & Roberson, B. (2010). The optimal defense of networks of targets. Purdue University, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Kovenock, D, Roberson, B Garfinkel, Michelle R, & Skaperdas, Stergios (2012). Conflicts with multiple battlefields. Oxford handbook of the economics of peace and conflict, New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Kovenock, D., Roberson, B., & Sheremeta, R. M. (2010). The attack and defense of weakest-link networks. Chapman University, Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kräkel, M (2008). Emotions in tournaments. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 67, 204214. 10.1016/j.jebo.2007.08.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kräkel, M., & Nieken, P. (2012). Relative performance pay in the shadow of crisis. University of Bonn, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Kräkel, M, Nieken, P, & Przemeck, J (2012). Risk taking and investing in electoral competition. European Journal of Political Economy, 2014(33), 98120.Google Scholar
Krishna, V, & Morgan, J (1997). An analysis of the war of attrition and the all-pay auction. Journal of Economic Theory, 72, 343362 0883.90054 10.1006/jeth.1996.2208CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krishna, V, Morgan, J, & Baye, MR (1998). The winner-take-all principle in small tournaments. Advances in applied microeconomics, Stamford, CT: JAI Press.Google Scholar
Krueger, AO (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review, 64, 291303.Google Scholar
Kugler, T, Rapoport, A, & Pazy, A (2010). Public good provision in inter-group conflicts: Effects of asymmetry and profit-sharing rule. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 23, 421438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuhnen, CM, & Tymula, A (2012). Feedback, self-esteem and performance in organizations. Management Science, 58, 94113. 10.1287/mnsc.1110.1379CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kvasov, D (2007). Contests with limited resources. Journal of Economic Theory, 136, 738748 1281.91090 2888432 10.1016/j.jet.2006.06.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lacomba, JA, Lagos, FM, Reuben, E, & van Winden, F (2014). On the escalation and de-escalation of conflict. Games and Economic Behavior, 86, 4057 1294.91041 3215494 10.1016/j.geb.2014.03.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landry, C, Lange, A, List, JA, Price, MK, & Rupp, N (2006). Toward an understanding of the economics of charity: Evidence from a field experiment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121, 747782. 10.1162/qjec.2006.121.2.747CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lange, A, List, JA, & Price, MK (2007). Using lotteries to finance public goods: Theory and experimental evidence. International Economic Review, 48, 901927 2336979 10.1111/j.1468-2354.2007.00449.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazear, EP (1999). Personnel economics past lessons and future directions—presidential address to the society of labor economists. Journal of Labor Economics, 17, 199236. 10.1086/209918CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazear, EP (2000). Performance pay and productivity. American Economic Review, 90, 13461361. 10.1257/aer.90.5.1346CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazear, EP, & Rosen, S (1981). Rank-order tournaments as optimum labor contracts. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 841864. 10.1086/261010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, D (2012). Weakest-link contest with group-specific public good prizes. European Journal of Political Economy, 28, 238248. 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2011.11.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leibbrandt, A, & Saaksvuori, L (2012). Communication in intergroup conflicts. European Economic Review, 56, 11361147. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2012.05.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leininger, W, & Yang, CL (1994). Dynamic rent-seeking games. Games and Economic Behavior, 7, 406427 0814.90141 1300312 10.1006/game.1994.1059CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leuven, E, Oosterbeek, H, Sonnemans, J, & van der Klaauw, B (2011). Incentives versus sorting in tournaments: Evidence from a field experiment. Journal of Labor Economics, 29, 637658. 10.1086/659345CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leuven, E, Oosterbeek, H, & van der Klaauw, B (2010). The effect of financial rewards on students’ achievement: Evidence from a randomized experiment. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8, 12431265.Google Scholar
Lim, N (2010). Social loss aversion and optimal contest design. Journal of Marketing Research, 47, 777787. 10.1509/jmkr.47.4.777CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lim, N, Ahearne, M, & Ham, SH (2009). Designing sales contests: Does the prize structure matter?. Journal of Marketing Research, 46, 356371. 10.1509/jmkr.46.3.356CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lim, W, Matros, A, & Turocy, TL (2014). Bounded rationality and group size in Tullock contests: Experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 99, 155167. 10.1016/j.jebo.2013.12.010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Linster, BG, Fullerton, RL, Mckee, M, & Slate, S (2001). Rent-seeking models of international competition: An experimental investigation. Defence and Peace Economics, 12, 285302. 10.1080/10430710108404989CrossRefGoogle Scholar
List, J. A., van Soest, D., Stoop, J., & Zhou, H. (2014). On the role of group size in tournaments: Theory and evidence from lab and field experiments. NBER, Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, TX, Yang, J, Adamic, LA, & Chen, Y (2014). Crowdsourcing with all-pay auctions: A field experiment on Taskcn. Management Science, 60, 20202037. 10.1287/mnsc.2013.1845CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Long, NV, & Vousden, N (1987). Risk-averse rent seeking with shared rents. Economic Journal, 97, 971985. 10.2307/2233083CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ludwig, S, & Lunser, GK (2012). Observing your competitor—The role of effort information in two-stage tournaments. Journal of Economic Psychology, 33, 166182. 10.1016/j.joep.2011.09.011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lugovskyy, V, Puzzello, D, & Tucker, S (2010). An experimental investigation of overdissipation in the all pay auction. European Economic Review, 54, 974997. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2010.02.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mago, S. D., Savikhin, A. C., & Sheremeta, R. M. (2014). Facing your opponents: Social identification and information feedback in contests. Journal of Conflict Resolution, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Mago, S. D., & Sheremeta, R. M. (2014). Multi-battle contests: An experimental study. Economic Science Institute, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Mago, SD, Sheremeta, RM, & Yates, A (2013). Best-of-three contest experiments: Strategic versus psychological momentum. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 31, 287296. 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2012.11.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Masiliunas, A., Mengel, F., & Reiss, J. P. (2012). Behavioral variation in Tullock contests. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Matros, A, & Armanios, D (2009). Tullock contest with reimbursements. Public Choice, 141, 4963. 10.1007/s11127-009-9436-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maynard Smith, J (1974). Theory of games and the evolution of animal contests. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 47, 209221 444115 10.1016/0022-5193(74)90110-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McBride, M, & Skaperdas, S (2014). Conflict, Settlement, and the Shadow of the Future,”. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 105, 7589. 10.1016/j.jebo.2014.04.023CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDonald, J., & Tukey, J. (1949). Colonel Blotto: A problem of military strategy. Fortune, June.Google Scholar
McKelvey, R, & Palfrey, T (1995). Quantal response equilibria for normal form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 638 0832.90126 1347932 10.1006/game.1995.1023CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michelitch, K. (2009). Do quotas make gender and ethnic groups expend less effort in competition? Working Paper.Google Scholar
Millner, EL, & Pratt, MD (1989). An experimental investigation of efficient rent-seeking. Public Choice, 62, 139151. 10.1007/BF00124330CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Millner, EL, & Pratt, MD (1991). Risk aversion and rent-seeking: An extension and some experimental evidence. Public Choice, 69, 8192. 10.1007/BF00123856CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minor, D. (2012). Coarse thinking and competition. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Moldovanu, B, & Sela, A (2001). The optimal allocation of prizes in contests. American Economic Review, 91, 542558. 10.1257/aer.91.3.542CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moldovanu, B, Sela, A, & Shi, X (2007). Contests for status. Journal of Political Economy, 115, 338363. 10.1086/518010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montero, M., Possajennikov, A., Sefton, M., & Turocy, T. L. (2014). The value of votes in weighted voting games: Majoritarian contests with asymmetric battlefields. University of Nottingham, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Morgan, J, Orzen, H, & Sefton, M (2012). Endogenous entry in contests. Economic Theory, 51, 435463 1262.91019 2983359 10.1007/s00199-010-0544-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, J, & Sefton, M (2000). Funding public goods with lotteries: experimental evidence. Review of Economic Studies, 67, 785810 1119.91329 1800327 10.1111/1467-937X.00154CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Müller, W, & Schotter, A (2010). Workaholics and dropouts in organizations. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8, 717743. 10.1111/j.1542-4774.2010.tb00538.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nagel, R (1995). Unraveling in guessing games: An experimental study. American Economic Review, 85, 13131326.Google Scholar
Nalbantian, HR, & Schotter, A (1997). Productivity under group incentives: An experimental study. American Economic Review, 87, 314341.Google Scholar
Nalebuff, BJ, & Stiglitz, JE (1983). Prizes and incentives: Towards a general theory of compensation and competition. Bell Journal of Economics, 14, 2143. 10.2307/3003535CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niederle, M., Segal, C., & Vesterlund, L. (2013). How costly is diversity? Affirmative action in light of gender differences in competitiveness. Management Science, 59, 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niederle, M, & Vesterlund, L (2007). Do women shy away from competition? Do men compete too much?. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122, 10671101. 10.1162/qjec.122.3.1067CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niederle, M, & Vesterlund, L (2011). Gender and competition. Annual Review of Economics, 3, 601630. 10.1146/annurev-economics-111809-125122CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nieken, P (2010). On the choice of risk and effort in tournaments-Experimental evidence. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 19(3), 811840. 10.1111/j.1530-9134.2010.00270.xGoogle Scholar
Noussair, C, & Silver, J (2006). Behavior in all pay auctions with incomplete information. Games and Economic Behavior, 55, 189206 1138.91409 2212019 10.1016/j.geb.2005.01.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Öncüler, A, & Croson, R (2005). Rent-seeking for a risky rent—A model and experimental investigation. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 17, 403429. 10.1177/0951629805056895CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Onderstal, S, Schram, AJHC, & Soetevent, AR (2013). Bidding to give in the field. Journal of Public Economics, 105, 7285. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2013.04.011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ong, D., & Chen, Z. (2013). Tiger women: An all-pay auction experiment on gender signaling of desire to win. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Oprea, R, Wilson, BJ, & Zillante, A (2013). War of attrition: Evidence from a laboratory experiment on market exit. Economic Inquiry, 51, 20182027. 10.1111/ecin.12014CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orrison, A, Schotter, A, & Weigelt, K (2004). Multiperson tournaments: an experimental examination. Management Science, 50, 268279. 10.1287/mnsc.1030.0128CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orzen, H. (2008). Fundraising through competition: Evidence from the lab. CeDEx, Working paper.Google Scholar
Otsubo, H, & Rapoport, A (2008). Dynamic volunteer’s dilemma in finite and discrete time: Theory and experimental evidence. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 52, 961984. 10.1177/0022002708321401CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parco, J, Rapoport, A, & Amaldoss, W (2005). Two-stage contests with budget constraints: An experimental study. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 49, 320338 1095.91006 2160403 10.1016/j.jmp.2005.03.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phillips, O, & Mason, C (1997). Wars of attrition in experimental duopoly markets. Southern Economic Journal, 63, 726742. 10.2307/1061105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Potters, JC, De Vries, CG, & Van Winden, F (1998). An experimental examination of rational rent seeking. European Journal of Political Economy, 14, 783800. 10.1016/S0176-2680(98)00037-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prendergast, C (1999). The provision of incentives in firms. Journal of Economic Literature, 37, 763. 10.1257/jel.37.1.7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Price, CR, & Sheremeta, RM (2011). Endowment effects in contests. Economics Letters, 111, 217219 2841663 10.1016/j.econlet.2011.02.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Price, C. R., & Sheremeta, R. M. (2014). Endowment origin, demographic effects and individual preferences in contests. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Riley, JG, & Samuelson, WF (1981). Optimal auctions. American Economic Review, 71, 381392.Google Scholar
Roberson, B (2006). The Colonel Blotto game. Economic Theory, 29, 124 1107.91010 2247789 2006ittc.book.....R 10.1007/s00199-005-0071-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roberson, B, & Kvasov, D (2012). The non-constant sum Colonel Blotto game. Economic Theory, 51, 397433 1262.91088 2983358 10.1007/s00199-011-0673-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosen, S (1986). Prizes and incentives in elimination tournaments. American Economic Review, 76, 701715 1986ssps.conf.....RGoogle Scholar
Ryvkin, D (2010). Contests with private costs: beyond two players. European Journal of Political Economy, 26, 558567. 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2010.09.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ryvkin, D (2011). Fatigue in dynamic tournaments. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 20, 10111041. 10.1111/j.1530-9134.2011.00314.xGoogle Scholar
Sacco, D., & Schmutzler, A. (2008). All-pay auctions with negative prize externalities: Theory and experimental evidence. Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Savikhin, AC, & Sheremeta, RM (2013). Simultaneous decision-making in competitive and cooperative games. Economic Inquiry, 51, 13111323. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2012.00474.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sbriglia, P, & Hey, JD (1994). Experiments in multi-stage R&D competition. Empirical Economics, 19, 291316. 10.1007/BF01175876CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, T (1960). The strategy of conflict, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schmitt, P, Shupp, R, Swope, K, & Cadigan, J (2004). Multi-period rent-seeking contests with carryover: Theory and experimental evidence. Economics of Governance, 5, 187211. 10.1007/s10101-004-0075-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schotter, A, & Weigelt, K (1992). Asymmetric tournaments, equal opportunity laws, and affirmative action: Some experimental results. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 511539. 10.2307/2118480CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schram, A, & Onderstal, AM (2009). Bidding to give: an experimental comparison of auctions for charity. International Economic Review, 50, 431457 2504667 10.1111/j.1468-2354.2009.00536.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sheremeta, RM (2010). Expenditures and information disclosure in two-stage political contests. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 54, 771798. 10.1177/0022002710364125CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sheremeta, RM (2010). Experimental comparison of multi-stage and one-stage contests. Games and Economic Behavior, 68, 731747 1200.91071 2655232 10.1016/j.geb.2009.08.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sheremeta, RM (2011). Contest design: An experimental investigation. Economic Inquiry, 49, 573590. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2009.00274.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sheremeta, RM (2011). Perfect-substitutes, best-shot, and weakest-link contests between groups. Korean Economic Review, 27, 532.Google Scholar
Sheremeta, RM (2013). Overbidding and heterogeneous behavior in contest experiments. Journal of Economic Surveys, 27, 491514. 10.1111/joes.12022CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sheremeta, RM Congleton, RD, & Hillman, AL (2015). Behavioral dimensions of contests. Companion to political economy of rent seeking, London: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Sheremeta, R. M., & Wu, S. Y. (2011). Optimal tournament design and incentive response: An experimental investigation of canonical tournament theory. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Sheremeta, RM, & Zhang, J (2010). Can groups solve the problem of over-bidding in contests?. Social Choice and Welfare, 35, 175197 1194.91065 2658211 10.1007/s00355-009-0434-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shogren, JF, & Baik, KH (1992). Favorites and underdogs: Strategic behavior in an experimental contest. Public Choice, 74, 191205. 10.1007/BF00140767CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shupp, R, Sheremeta, RM, Schmidt, D, & Walker, J (2013). Resource allocation contests: Experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Psychology, 39, 257267. 10.1016/j.joep.2013.09.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Silipo, DB (2005). The evolution of cooperation in patent races: Theory and experimental evidence. Journal of Economics, 85, 138 1132.91512 10.1007/s00712-005-0115-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sisak, D (2009). Multiple-prize contests—The optimal allocation of prizes. Journal of Economic Surveys, 23, 82114. 10.1111/j.1467-6419.2008.00557.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stahl, D, & Wilson, P (1994). Experimental evidence on players’ models of other players. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 25, 309327. 10.1016/0167-2681(94)90103-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stein, W (2002). Asymmetric rent-seeking with more than two contestants. Public Choice, 113, 325336. 10.1023/A:1020877410243CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stracke, R, Höchtl, W, Kerschbamer, R, & Sunde, U (2014). Optimal prizes in dynamic elimination contests: An experimental analysis. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 102, 4358. 10.1016/j.jebo.2014.02.018CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stracke, R., Höchtl, W., Kerschbamer, R., & Sunde, U. (2014b). Incentives and selection in promotion contests: Is it possible to kill two birds with one stone?. Managerial and Decision Economics, Forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sutter, M, & Strassmair, C (2009). Communication, cooperation and collusion in team tournaments—An experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior, 66, 506525 1161.91340 2527787 10.1016/j.geb.2008.02.014CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Szentes, B, & Rosenthal, RW (2003). Three-object two-bidder simultaneous auctions: chopsticks and tetrahedra. Games and Economic Behavior, 44, 114133 1057.91035 1985009 10.1016/S0899-8256(02)00530-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Szymanski, S (2003). The economic design of sporting contests. Journal of Economic Literature, 41, 11371187. 10.1257/jel.41.4.1137CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Szymanski, S, & Valletti, TM (2005). Incentive effects of second prizes. European Journal of Political Economy, 21, 467481. 10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2004.07.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, CR (1995). Digging for golden carrots: An analysis of research tournaments. American Economic Review, 85, 872890.Google Scholar
Treich, N (2010). Risk-aversion and prudence in rent-seeking games. Public Choice, 145, 339349. 10.1007/s11127-009-9569-xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, G (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5, 224232.Google Scholar
Tullock, G Buchanan, James M, Tollison, Robert D, & Tullock, Gordon (1980). Efficient rent seeking. Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society, College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press 97112.Google Scholar
Van Dijk, F, Sonnemans, J, & van Winden, F (2001). Incentives systems in a real effort experiment. European Economic Review, 45, 187214. 10.1016/S0014-2921(00)00056-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vandegrift, D, Yavas, A, & Brown, P (2007). Incentive effects and overcrowding in tournaments: An experimental analysis. Experimental Economics, 10, 345368 1142.91392 10.1007/s10683-006-9138-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vasilaky, K. (2011). Incentives for information exchange: Getting women to share in rural Uganda. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Vogt, C, Weimann, J, & Yang, CL (2002). Efficient rent-seeking in experiment. Public Choice, 110, 6778. 10.1023/A:1013051501754CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wärneryd, K (2003). Information in conflicts. Journal of Economic Theory, 110, 121136 1048.91054 1984256 10.1016/S0022-0531(03)00006-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wasser, C (2013). Incomplete information in rent-seeking contests. Economic Theory, 53, 239268 1273.91287 3063292 10.1007/s00199-011-0688-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weigelt, K, Dukerich, J, & Schotter, A (1989). Reactions to discrimination in an incentive pay compensation scheme: A game-theoretic approach. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 44, 2644. 10.1016/0749-5978(89)90033-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weimann, J, Yang, CL, & Vogt, C (2000). An experiment on sequential rent seeking. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 41, 405426. 10.1016/S0167-2681(99)00083-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wu, SY, & Roe, B (2005). Behavioral and welfare effects of tournaments and fixed performance contracts: Some experimental evidence. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 87, 130146. 10.1111/j.0002-9092.2005.00707.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wu, S. Y., Roe, B., & Sporleder, T. (2006). Mixed tournaments, common shocks, and disincentives: An experimental study. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Young, HP, & Ordeshook, Peter C (1978). A tactical lobbying game. Game theory and political science, New York: New York University Press 391404.Google Scholar
Zizzo, DJ (2002). Racing with uncertainty: A patent race experiment. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 20, 877902. 10.1016/S0167-7187(01)00087-XCrossRefGoogle Scholar