Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-v2ckm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T14:19:25.006Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Silence is golden: team problem solving and communication costs

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Gary Charness*
Affiliation:
University of California – Santa Barbara, Santa Barbara, USA
David J. Cooper*
Affiliation:
Florida State University, Tallahassee, USA University of East Anglia, Norwich, UK
Zachary Grossman*
Affiliation:
Florida State University, Tallahassee, USA

Abstract

We conduct experiments comparing the performance of individuals and teams of four subjects in solving two rather different tasks. The first involves nonograms, logic puzzles that require a series of incremental steps to solve. The second task uses CRT-type questions, which require a single, specific insight. Contrary to the existing literature, team performance in both tasks is statistically indistinguishable from that of individuals when communication is costless. If a tiny message cost is imposed, team performance improves and becomes statistically better than that of individuals, although still worse than previous research on teams would have suggested. To the best of our knowledge, our study is the first to find that imposing friction on communication leads to more effective performance in teams. Message costs reduce the quantity of messages but increase the quality, specifically the mix of good and bad suggestions. The improved quality of communication with message costs allows teams to out-perform individuals. Our analysis suggests that organizations would do better by identifying an able individual to perform an intellective task rather than using teams; prediction exercises indicate that this will not harm, and will generally increase, performance relative to a team, and only requires the cost of paying one individual rather than many.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2019 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-019-09627-w) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

“Silence is golden …”

—The Four Seasons

References

Arechar, A, Kraft-Todd, G, & Rand, D (2017). Turking overtime: How participant characteristics and behavior vary over time and day on Amazon Mechanical Turk. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 3(1), 111. 10.1007/s40881-017-0035-0CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Baron, J, Scott, S, Fincher, K, & Metz, S (2015). Why does the Cognitive Reflection Test (sometimes) predict utilitarian moral judgment (and other things)?. Journal of Applied Research in Memory and Cognition, 4, 265284. 10.1016/j.jarmac.2014.09.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Ner, A, & Putterman, L (2009). Trust, communication, and contracts: An experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 70(1–2), 106121. 10.1016/j.jebo.2009.01.011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Ner, A, Putterman, L, & Ren, T (2011). Lavish returns on cheap talk: Non-binding communication in a trust experiment. Journal of Socio-Economics, 40, 113. 10.1016/j.socec.2010.09.009Google Scholar
Blume, A., Kriss, P., & Weber, R. (2016a). Pre-play communication with forgone costly messages: Experimental evidence on forward induction. CESIFO Working Paper No. 5958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blume, A., Kriss, P., & Weber, R. (2016b). Coordination with decentralized costly communication. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization..CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J, Charness, G, & Ellman, M (2016). Let’s talk: How communication affects contract design. Journal of the European Economic Association, 14(4), 943974. 10.1111/jeea.12157CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casari, M, Zhang, J, & Jackson, C (2016). Same process, different outcomes: Group performance in an acquiring a company experiment. Experimental Economics, 19(4), 764791. 10.1007/s10683-015-9467-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, TN, & Mui, VL (2014). Coordinating resistance through communication and repeated interaction. The Economic Journal, 124(574), F226F256. 10.1111/ecoj.12088CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Dufwenberg, M (2006). Promises and partnership. Econometrica, 74, 15791601. 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00719.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Dufwenberg, M (2011). Participation. American Economic Review, 101, 12111237. 10.1257/aer.101.4.1211CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, Karni, E, & Levin, D (2007). Individual and group decision making under risk: An experimental study of Bayesian updating and violations of first-order stochastic dominance. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 35, 129148. 10.1007/s11166-007-9020-yCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, Karni, E, & Levin, D (2010). On the conjunction fallacy in probability judgment: New experimental evidence regarding Linda. Games and Economic Behavior, 68, 551556. 10.1016/j.geb.2009.09.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Sutter, M (2012). Groups make better self-interested decisions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26, 157176. 10.1257/jep.26.3.157CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, D, & Kagel, J (2005). Are two heads better than one? Team versus individual play in signaling games. American Economic Review, 95, 477509. 10.1257/0002828054201431CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, D, & Kagel, J (2009). The role of context and team play in cross-game learning. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(5), 11011139. 10.1162/JEEA.2009.7.5.1101CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, D, & Kagel, J (2016). A failure to communicate: An experimental investigation of the effects of advice on strategic play. European Economic Review, 82, 2445. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2015.10.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, D., & Kagel, J. (2018). Learning and contagion in teams. Working paper. Department of Economics, Florida State University.Google Scholar
Cooper, D, & Kühn, K-U (2014). Communication, renegotiation, and the scope for collusion. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 6(2), 247278.Google Scholar
Cooper, D, & Sutter, M (2018). Endogenous role assignment and team performance. International Economic Review, 59(3), 15471569. 10.1111/iere.12313CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, D, Weber, R Capra, M, Croson, R, Rigdon, M, & Rosenblatt, T (2019). Recent advances in experimental coordination games. The handbook of experimental economic game theory, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Davis, JH (1992). Some compelling intuitions about group consensus decisions, theoretical and empirical research, and interpersonal aggregation phenomena: Selected examples, 1950–1990. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 52, 338. 10.1016/0749-5978(92)90044-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frederick, S (2005). Cognitive reflection and decision making. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(4), 2542. 10.1257/089533005775196732CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: Organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1(1), 114125. 10.1007/s40881-015-0004-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, RM, & Walker, JM (1988). Communication and free-riding behavior: The voluntary contribution mechanism. Economic Inquiry, 26(4), 585608. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.1988.tb01519.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isopi, A, Nosenzo, D, & Starmer, C (2011). Does consultation improve decision-making?. Theory and Decision, 77(3), 377388. 10.1007/s11238-014-9449-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kremer, M (1993). The O-ring theory of economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3), 551575. 10.2307/2118400CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lorge, I, & Solomon, H (1955). Two models of group behavior in the solution of eureka-type problems. Psychometrika, 20, I39I148. 10.1007/BF02288986CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oldrati, V, Patricelli, J, Colombo, B, & Antonietti, A (2016). The role of dorsolateral prefrontal cortex in inhibition mechanism: A study on cognitive reflection test and similar tasks through neuromodulation. Neuropsychologia, 91, 499508. 10.1016/j.neuropsychologia.2016.09.010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Primi, C, Morsanyi, K, Chiesi, F, Donati, M, & Hamilton, J (2016). The development and testing of a new version of the cognitive reflection test applying Item Response Theory (IRT). Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 29(5), 453469. 10.1002/bdm.1883CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shaw, M (1932). A comparison of individuals and small groups in the rational solution of complex problems. American Journal of Psychology, 44, 491504. 10.2307/1415351CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomson, K, & Oppenheimer, D (2016). Investigating an alternate form of the cognitive reflection test. Judgment and Decision Making, 11(1), 99113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Toplak, M, West, R, & Stanovich, K (2014). Assessing miserly information processing: An expansion of the Cognitive Reflection Test. Thinking & Reasoning, 20, 147168. 10.1080/13546783.2013.844729CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, A. (2014). Costly communication in groups: Theory and an experiment. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Charness et al. supplementary material

Appendices A-C
Download Charness et al. supplementary material(File)
File 52.9 KB