Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-nzzs5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T08:52:33.639Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Shifting the blame to a powerless intermediary

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Regine Oexl*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Innsbruck, Universitaetsstrasse 15, 6020 Innsbruck, Austria
Zachary J. Grossman
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of California, Santa Barbara, 2127 North Hall, 93106 Santa Barbara, CA, USA

Abstract

We extend the results of Bartling and Fischbacher (Rev. Econ. Stud. 79(1):67–87, 2012) by showing that, by delegating to an intermediary, a dictator facing an allocation decision can effectively shift blame onto the delegee even when doing so necessarily eliminates the possibility of a fair outcome. Dictators choosing selfishly via an intermediary are punished less and earn greater profits than those who do so directly. Despite being powerless to influence the fairness of the outcome, an intermediary given the choice between two unfair outcomes is punished more than when the dictator chooses one directly. This is not the case when the intermediary merely can initiate the random selection of one of the outcomes. Our findings reinforce and clarify the usefulness of agency as a tool to evade perceived culpability.

Type
Manuscript
Copyright
Copyright © 2012 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic Supplementary Material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-012-9335-7) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Bartling, B., & Fischbacher, U. (2012). Shifting the blame: on delegation and responsibility. Review of Economic Studies, 79(1), 6787. 10.1093/restud/rdr023CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review, 90(1), 166193. 10.1257/aer.90.1.166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 817869. 10.1162/003355302760193904CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coffman, L. C. (2011). Intermediation reduces punishment (and reward). American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 3(4), 77106. 10.1257/mic.3.4.77Google Scholar
Dana, J., Cain, D. M., & Dawes, R. M. (2006). What you don’t know won’t hurt me: costly (but quiet) exit in dictator games. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 100(2), 193201. 10.1016/j.obhdp.2005.10.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dana, J., Weber, R., & Kuang, J. (2007). Exploiting moral wiggle room: experiments demonstrating an illusory preference for fairness. Economic Theory, 33(1), 6780. 10.1007/s00199-006-0153-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M., & Kirchsteiger, G. (2004). A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47(2), 268298. 10.1016/j.geb.2003.06.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817868. 10.1162/003355399556151CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fershtman, C., & Gneezy, U. (2001). Strategic delegation: an experiment. Rand Journal of Economics, 32(2), 352368. 10.2307/2696414CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B. (2003). An online recruitment system for economic experiments. Forschung und Wissenschaftliches Rechnen, 63, 7993.Google Scholar
Grossman, Z. (2010). Strategic ignorance and the robustness of social preferences (Tech. Rep. 1469100). Economics Working Paper Series, Department of Economics, University of California, Santa Barbara.Google Scholar
Hamman, J. R., Loewenstein, G., & Weber, R. A. (2010). Self-interest through delegation: an additional rationale for the principal-agent relationship. American Economic Review, 100(4), 18261846. 10.1257/aer.100.4.1826CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazear, E. P., Malmendier, U., & Weber, R. A. (2012). Sorting in experiments with application to social preferences. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 4(1), 136163. 10.1257/app.4.1.136Google Scholar
Paharia, N., Kassam, K. S., Greene, J. D., & Bazerman, M. H. (2009). Dirty work, clean hands: the moral psychology of indirect agency. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 109(2), 134141. 10.1016/j.obhdp.2009.03.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Oexl and Grossman supplementary material

A Supplemental Results
Download Oexl and Grossman supplementary material(File)
File 311.9 KB