Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-7g5wt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T16:03:23.151Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

More than words: the effects of cheap talk in a volunteer’s dilemma

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Christoph Feldhaus*
Affiliation:
University of Cologne, Albertus-Magnus-Platz, 50923 Cologne, Germany
Julia Stauf
Affiliation:
University of Cologne, Albertus-Magnus-Platz, 50923 Cologne, Germany

Abstract

We theoretically and experimentally investigate a game in which exactly one person should make a costly effort to achieve a socially efficient outcome. This setting is commonly known as the volunteer’s dilemma. We implement one-way communication by allowing one player to send a message indicating whether she intends to volunteer and investigate the message’s effects on behavior and efficiency in the subsequent game. We theoretically demonstrate that there are asymmetric mixed-strategy equilibria in the volunteer’s dilemma and argue that one of these is likely to emerge through one-way communication. The experimental data support this notion. We find that the actions of both the sender and receiver of the message are crucially affected by the cheap talk stage and that efficiency in the volunteer’s dilemma increases with one-way communication.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2015 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-015-9442-3) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Aumann, RJ Gabszewicz, JJ, Richard, J-F, & Wolsey, LA (1990). Nash equilibria are not self-enforcing. Economic decision-making: Games, econometrics and optimization, Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Baliga, S, & Morris, S (2002). Co-ordination, spillovers, and cheap talk. Journal of Economic Theory, 105(2), 450468. 10.1006/jeth.2001.2855CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blume, A, & Ortmann, A (2007). The effects of costless pre-play communication: Experimental evidence from games with pareto-ranked equilibria. Journal of Economic Theory, 132(1), 274290. 10.1016/j.jet.2005.03.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burton, A, & Sefton, M (2004). Risk, pre-play communication and equilibrium. Games and Economic Behavior, 46(1), 2340. 10.1016/S0899-8256(03)00115-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, R, DeJong, DV, Forsythe, R, & Ross, TW (1989). Communication in the battle of the sexes game: Some experimental results. RAND Journal of Economics, 20(4), 568587. 10.2307/2555734CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, R, DeJong, DV, Forsythe, R, & Ross, TW (1992). Communication in coordination games. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 739771. 10.2307/2118488CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, V (1998). A survey of experiments on communication via cheap talk. Journal of Economic Theory, 78(2), 286298. 10.1006/jeth.1997.2359CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Darley, JM, & Latané, B (1968). Bystander intervention in emergencies: Diffusion of responsibility. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 8(41), 377383. 10.1037/h0025589CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Devetag, G, & Ortmann, A (2007). When and why? A critical survey on coordination failure in the laboratory. Experimental Economics, 10(3), 331344. 10.1007/s10683-007-9178-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diekmann, A (1985). Volunteer’s dilemma. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 29(4), 605610. 10.1177/0022002785029004003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diekmann, A (1993). Cooperation in an asymmetric volunteer’s dilemma game: theory and experimental evidence. International Journal of Game Theory, 22, 7585. 10.1007/BF01245571CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farrell, J (1987). Cheap talk, coordination, and entry. RAND Journal of Economics, 18(1), 3439. 10.2307/2555533CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farrell, J, & Rabin, M (1996). Cheap talk. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(3), 103118. 10.1257/jep.10.3.103CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U (2007). Z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, U (2005). Deception: The role of consequences. American Economic Review, 95(1), 384394. 10.1257/0002828053828662CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B Kremer, K, & Macho, V (2004). An online recruitment system for economic experiments. Forschung und wissenschaftliches rechnen 2003, Goettingen: Gesellschaft fuer Wissenschaftliche Datenverarbeitung 7993.Google Scholar
Myatt, DP, & Wallace, C (2008). An evolutionary analysis of the volunteer’s dilemma. Games and Economic Behavior, 62(1), 6776. 10.1016/j.geb.2007.03.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stauf, J. (2012). Essays on behavior under risk and uncertainty. Dissertation, University of Cologne.Google Scholar
Van Huyck, J, Battalio, R, & Beil, R (1990). Tacit coordination games, strategic uncertainty, and coordination failure. American Economic Review, 80(1), 234248.Google Scholar
Van Huyck, J, Battalio, R, & Beil, R (1991). Strategic uncertainty, equilibrium selection, and coordination failure in average opinion games. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(3), 885911. 10.2307/2937932CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weesie, J (1993). Asymmetry and timing in the volunteer’s dilemma. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 37(3), 569590. 10.1177/0022002793037003008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weesie, J (1994). Incomplete information and timing in the volunteer’s dilemma: A comparison of four models. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 38, 557585. 10.1177/0022002794038003008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Feldhaus and Stauf supplementary material

Online Appendix 1: Instructions for the one-way communication treatment T2 (translation from German)
Download Feldhaus and Stauf supplementary material(File)
File 28.8 KB