Hostname: page-component-669899f699-7tmb6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-04-25T16:20:32.370Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Moving from nudging to boosting: empowering behaviour change to address global challenges

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 April 2025

Ralph Hertwig*
Affiliation:
Center for Adaptive Rationality, Max Planck Institute for Human Development, Berlin, Germany
Susan Michie
Affiliation:
Centre for Behaviour Change, University College London, London, UK
Robert West
Affiliation:
Institute of Epidemiology and Health Care, University College London, London, UK
Stephen Reicher
Affiliation:
School of Psychology, University of St. Andrews, St. Andrews, UK
*
Corresponding author: Ralph Hertwig; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The COVID-19 pandemic provided a stark reminder that societies will struggle to address global challenges unless they are able to change behaviour at scale. The widely adopted ‘nudge’ approach epitomizes an individualistic, deficit model of human cognition and motivation that leverages or overcomes people’s weaknesses and biases to get them to do things they would otherwise not. By contrast, we argue that tackling the challenges facing humanity requires a collective, capacity-building approach – one that boosts the competences, opportunities, and motivations of individuals to act together.

Type
Perspective
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press.

Introduction

Human behaviour can be both the cause of and the solution to many global challenges, including pandemics, non-communicable diseases, antimicrobial resistance, the climate and biodiversity crisis, democratic backsliding, and violent conflicts. A recent example is the COVID-19 pandemic (‘Behaviour fuels, and fights, pandemics’, 2020). Public policies to contain the spread of the virus included attempts to change people’s everyday behaviours, such as reducing physical contact and spatial proximity to others, wearing masks, and frequent handwashing. People were also expected to adopt specific protective behaviours such as regular testing, adhering to isolation guidelines, getting vaccinated, acquiring and understanding novel information and concepts (e.g., exponential growth), and building on or developing new competences such as coping with anxiety when under economic strain, dealing with loneliness in the face of self-isolation and quarantine requirements, cultivating social relationships under profoundly different conditions, considering the perspectives and concerns of others (e.g., people at risk), coordinating and cooperating with others, communicating with respect, migrating to online environments, developing effective work-from-home arrangements, and managing conflicting demands (Kniffin et al., Reference Kniffin, Narayanan, Anseel, Antonakis, Ashford, Bakker, Bamberger, Bapuji, Bhave, Choi, Creary, Demerouti, Flynn, Gelfand, Greer, Johns, Kesebir, Klein, Lee, Ozcelik, Petriglieri, Rothbard, Rudolph, Shaw, Sirola, Wanberg, Whillans, Wilmot and van Vugt2021).

Behavioural science can play an important role in understanding why people behave as they do and how societies can affect behaviour change to meet global challenges (Hallsworth, Reference Hallsworth2023). One popular approach has been labelled ‘nudging’. The nudge approach is based on the idea that human decision-making is often subject to severe limitations that need to be overcome or leveraged, and that small changes to the way that decisions are presented can ‘nudge’ people to make better choices, without them necessarily being aware of it. We argue that the opposite of this approach is what is needed – one that builds on people’s strengths, not just as individuals but as social animals with the ability and motivation to act collectively.

The nudge approach to behaviour change

Nudging is rooted in the idea that ‘small and apparently insignificant details can have major impacts on people’s behavior’ (Thaler et al., Reference Thaler, Sunstein, Balz and Shafir2013, 428–29) and that leveraging such subtle effects is preferable to applying more overt ways of influencing behaviour, such as support, persuasion, incentives, or coercion. To encourage healthier diets, for example, nudging steers clear of instruments like banning products, restricting advertising, or increasing costs through taxation. Instead, it focuses on how and where unhealthy products are displayed in shops or canteens (Bucher et al., Reference Bucher, Collins, Rollo, McCaffrey, De Vlieger, Van der Bend, Truby and Perez-Cueto2016; Cadario and Chandon, Reference Cadario and Chandon2020). By rearranging products so that healthier options are more prominently featured and easier to access, nudging aims to direct people towards choices that are in their long-term best interests.

Nudging exemplifies a ‘deficit’ model of human behaviour, according to which people’s decision-making processes are inherently limited. Cass Sunstein, who together with Richard Thaler invented and popularized the nudge concept, has argued that many consumers struggle with ‘inadequate information and behavioral biases, which can produce internalities, understood as costs that people impose on their future selves’ (Sunstein, Reference Sunstein2024, 1). In other words, due to informational, cognitive, and motivational limitations, people often make choices that have negative consequences for their future well-being. The nudge approach proposes that behavioural engineers can leverage such limitations – including overconfidence, loss aversion, status quo bias, framing effects, lack of self-control, myopia, inertia, inattention, and error-prone heuristics – to steer people into doing what is in their interests. In short, nudges are’ called for because of flaws in individual decision-making, and they work by making use of those flaws’ (Hausman and Welch, Reference Hausman and Welch2010, 126).

The mechanisms of nudging

Nudges can be divided into two broad categories: architectural and educative (Sunstein, Reference Sunstein2022). Architectural nudges target the choice architecture, or how choices are presented to people. This can include the placement of options in a list or their physical location in space, the language used to present them, and whether people have to opt in or out of them. For instance, placing healthier foods at eye level in a shop is a form of architectural nudging. Educative nudges involve providing warnings, reminders, and information to guide decision-making. This includes communicating descriptive norms informing people about others’ behaviour (Cialdini, Reference Cialdini2007). For example, a sign in a hotel bathroom saying ‘75% of our guests reuse their towels to protect the environment’ encourages people to follow the majority’s eco-friendly behaviour.

The nudge approach has been described as a form of libertarian paternalism (Thaler and Sunstein, Reference Thaler and Sunstein2003). It is paternalistic because an external authority prompts people to act in ways that the authority has decided is beneficial, individually and/or collectively. It is libertarian because it maintains freedom of choice and does not remove options or force people to act in a particular way.

The appeal of nudging

The nudge approach has proved popular among policymakers, arguably for several reasons. First, nudge policies can be highly cost-effective (Benartzi et al., Reference Benartzi, Beshears, Milkman, Sunstein, Thaler, Shankar, Tucker-Ray, Congdon and Galing2017). Even when they result in very small changes, they do so at low cost and the population-level impact can be significant (Halpern, Reference Halpern2015). Second, because nudging does not involve outright prohibitions or potentially costly support programmes, it appeals to governments that are averse to overt regulation and that advocate for fiscal conservatism and reduced government involvement in societal affairs (Halpern, Reference Halpern2015). Third, unlike other policy options, nudging does not require governments to take on corporate interests. A study of 11 countries that tried to impose sugar taxes on soft drinks, for example, found that all faced energetic lobbying and criticism (Lauber et al., Reference Lauber, Rippin, Wickramasinghe and Gilmore2022). Fourth, the nudge approach can absolve governments from their responsibility to address collective and societal problems. Framing issues like obesity, ill-health, and poverty as failures of individual decision-making diverts attention from systemic drivers of behaviour for which governments are responsible, such as allowing the production and dissemination of harmful products (Nestle, Reference Nestle2015; Kozyreva et al., Reference Kozyreva, Lewandowsky and Hertwig2020; Chater and Loewenstein, Reference Chater and Loewenstein2023). Fifth, nudge arguments align with broader views that politicians often hold about the public. The Hobbesian legitimization of government is that, left to themselves, individuals are incapable of creating a safe and stable society (Hobbes, Reference Hobbes1651/2016). Nudging can be seen as providing a ‘scientific’ justification for this viewpoint and a logical solution for societal problems. The more individuals are portrayed as cognitively and motivationally deficient, the more credible it becomes to blame them for societal issues and to cast nudging as a justifiable solution.

Limitations of the nudge approach

A key criticism of the nudge approach is that it deprioritizes overt and effective behaviour change strategies that are justifiably expensive or coercive, such as mass media campaigns to combat bullying, taxes on alcohol or sugary beverages, bans on smoking in public areas, financial incentives to reduce carbon emissions, and fines for polluting rivers (Chater and Loewenstein, Reference Chater and Loewenstein2023). While recognizing the validity of these criticisms, our focus here is on the individual deficit model that underpins the nudge approach. Two critical aspects of this model warrant closer examination: the view of humans as deficient and the focus on individual behaviour.

The deficit model of human cognition

Proponents of the nudge approach frequently refer to an extensive body of research – ‘thousands of studies’ (Thaler and Sunstein, Reference Thaler and Sunstein2021, 10) – purportedly showing that human thinking is flawed and biased. Indeed, the heuristics-and-biases programme, started by psychologists Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky in the early 1970s (Tversky and Kahneman, Reference Tversky and Kahneman1974), has profoundly changed how many psychologists and behavioural economists perceive the quality of people’s statistical reasoning, intuitions, inferences, and choices, as well as the cognitive mechanisms, or heuristics, that underlie these behaviours.

The main message of the heuristics-and-biases programme is a specific interpretation of Herbert Simon’s (Reference Simon1956) foundational concept of bounded rationality. Simon, a Nobel Prize laureate in economics, was a vocal critic of the rational choice framework – the classical model of rationality – as a descriptive model of human choice. He noted that this model expects individuals to have unlimited knowledge, computational power, and time to make perfectly rational decisions. Such an ‘Olympian model’ (Simon, Reference Simon1983, 19) of rational choice was perhaps suitable for omniscient gods, but unrealistic in the real world. As an alternative, Simon proposed the concept of bounded rationality, which acknowledges that people often approximate rather than optimize when making decisions.

Whereas Simon emphasized that people’s approximate decisions can be adaptive, good enough, and satisficing because the ‘environments to which [organisms] must adapt possess properties that permit further simplifications of its choice mechanisms’ (Simon, Reference Simon1956, 129), the heuristics-and-biases programme has interpreted bounded rationality to mean systematic biases in human judgment and choice. The research objective, as stated by Kahneman, was ‘to obtain a map of bounded rationality, by exploring the systematic biases that separate the beliefs that people have and the choices they make from the optimal beliefs and choices assumed in rational-agent models’ (Kahneman, Reference Kahneman2003, 1449). Richard Thaler, who worked closely with Kahneman and Tversky, famously reinforced this perspective by concluding that ‘mental illusions should be considered the rule rather than the exception’ (Thaler, Reference Thaler1991, 4).

The deficit view extends beyond cognitive deficits to include motivational deficiencies: the idea that people’s motivations are inherently maladaptive and that they cannot be trusted to do the right thing. Take the example of the UK government’s response to the COVID-19 pandemic. In early March 2020, the UK’s Chief Medical Officer, Chris Whitty, expressed concern that the public would be unable or unwilling to adhere to virus containment policies for long: ‘[T]here is a risk if we go too early, people will understandably get fatigued and it will be difficult to sustain … over time’ (The Telegraph, 2020). Similarly, the government feared that ‘anything too onerous suggested by the government … might be adopted enthusiastically for a few weeks but then people get bored and leave their homes just as the peak of the illness hits’ (Proctor, Reference Proctor2020). As senior cabinet minister Michael Gove testified to the UK COVID-19 Inquiry, there was a ‘broad view at the time that … the public … would not endure [lockdown measures] for long’ (UK Covid-19 Inquiry, 2023). Consequently, stay-at-home measures were only implemented on 23 March 2020, a delay that resulted in possibly tens of thousands of unnecessary deaths (Stewart and Sample, Reference Stewart and Sample2020).

Another example of the deficit view in the public discourse concerns democratic processes. A strand of libertarian scholars has challenged the quality and, by extension, the legitimacy of democratic decision-making. To support their ‘skepticism about democracy, these libertarians appeal to findings in cognitive and social psychology and political behavior to claim that decision making by ordinary citizens is unlikely to be rational or well grounded in evidence’ (Farrell et al., Reference Farrell, Mercier and Schwartzberg2023, 767). Voters are characterized as irrational (Caplan, Reference Caplan2008) and ‘systematically incompetent’ (Brennan, Reference Brennan2016, 201). Based on such arguments it has been asserted that ‘rule by demagogues … is the natural condition of democracy’ (Caplan, Reference Caplan2008, 19). There is no mincing of words when it is suggested that some individuals ‘ought not have the right to vote, or ought to have weaker voting rights than others’ (Brennan, Reference Brennan2016, viii). Additionally, it has been claimed that ‘widespread public ignorance is a type of pollution’ and that ‘democracy might function better if its powers were more tightly limited’ (Somin, Reference Somin2016, 6, 9).

The focus on individuals

Nudge theory focuses on individual decision-making. Yet this is often too narrow a focus, as illustrated by the ‘behavioural fatigue’ line adopted in the UK in the first wave of COVID-19. The assumption that people would not stick to stay-at-home measures for long was proven wrong; levels of adherence remained high despite psychological and economic hardships (Duffy and Allington, Reference Duffy and Allington2020). It soon became clear that a sense of shared identity and community was a critical factor in maintaining adherence (Jackson et al., Reference Jackson, Posch, Bradford, Hobson, Kyprianides and Yesberg2020), a finding subsequently corroborated by multiple studies (Stevenson et al., Reference Stevenson, Wakefield, Felsner, Drury and Costa2021; Van Bavel et al., Reference Van Bavel, Cichocka, Capraro, Sjåstad, Nezlek, Pavlović, Alfano, Gelfand, Azevedo, Birtel, Cislak, Lockwood, Ross, Abts, Agadullina, Aruta, Besharati, Bor, Choma, Crabtree, Cunningham, De, Ejaz, Elbaek and Boggio2022). This comes as no surprise to those who study mass behaviour in emergencies. Research has consistently shown that people tend not to panic or act destructively in crises (Johnson, Reference Johnson1987; Drury et al., Reference Drury, Novelli and Stott2013). Rather, a sense of common fate engenders a feeling of shared identity which, in turn, leads people to support and expect support from others (Drury, Reference Drury2018). This shared identity helps to sustain adherence to demanding measures in hard times.

Moreover, focusing solely on individual limitations neglects the crucial role of trust in behaviour change. Governments basing policy on an individual deficit model which assumes that people are neither willing nor able to make good choices are unlikely to use strategies known to build shared identity and trust, such as listening to the public, engaging with them, co-producing policy, and showing respect (Tyler and Blader, Reference Tyler and Blader2003; Bonell et al., Reference Bonell, Michie, Reicher, West, Bear, Yardley, Curtis, Amlôt and Rubin2020). Trust was vital to the success of public health responses during the COVID-19 pandemic (Bollyky et al., Reference Bollyky, Angelino, Wigley and Dieleman2022; Lenton et al., Reference Lenton, Boulton and Scheffer2022) and played a significant role in vaccine uptake, both internationally and in the UK (Paul et al., Reference Paul, Fancourt and Razai2022; Viskupič et al., Reference Viskupič, Wiltse and Meyer2022; Allington et al., Reference Allington, McAndrew, Moxham-Hall and Duffy2023). In autumn 2021, while over 90% of White Britons had been vaccinated, the figure for Black Britons was only around 60% (Dolby et al., Reference Dolby, Finning, Baker, Fowler-Dowd, Khunti, Razieh, Yates and Nafilyan2022). A lack of trust contributed to this disparity; 60% of Black Britons felt that health services were less concerned with their issues than with those of White people (Joint Committee on Human Rights, 2020). Addressing this mistrust through a process of engagement (Burgess et al., Reference Burgess, Osborne, Yongabi, Greenhalgh, Gurdasani and Kang2021) – by going to Black communities, working through community representatives, and listening and responding to concerns – proved highly effective (Halvorsrud et al., Reference Halvorsrud, Shand, Weil, Hutchings, Zuriaga, Satterthwaite, Yip, Eshareturi, Billett, Hepworth, Dodhia, Schwartz, Penniston, Mordaunt, Bulmer, Barratt, Illingworth, Inskip, Bury, Jenkins, Mounier-Jack and Raine2023). However, at a national level, such engagement was largely absent. Instead of fostering dialogue and trust, government representatives voiced disdain, labelling those who remained unvaccinated as ‘selfish.’ (BBC, Reference BBC2021).

An alternative approach to behaviour change based on boosting human abilities

An alternative to the individual deficit model of human cognition consists in identifying the social dynamics and human competences needed to tackle global challenges, and exploring how these can be harnessed and developed. We have already touched on the importance of social dynamics, such as building trust, strengthening communities, and fostering collective resilience (Reicher and Bauld, Reference Reicher and Bauld2021; Reicher, Reference Reicher2022). Here, we focus on human competences. In our view, the public’s ability to adapt to new challenges will depend not on superficial nudges but on sustained interventions and investments designed to develop human capital.

Boosting competences

The boosting approach to behavioural public policy works by harnessing and building on human strengths (Hertwig and Grüne-Yanoff, Reference Hertwig and Grüne-Yanoff2017). Boosts are interventions designed to improve people’s competences to make informed choices that align with their goals, preferences, and desires. To illustrate, Table 1 lists six societal challenges alongside the competences needed to address them and boost interventions that have proved successful in developing those competences.

Table 1. Six examples of global challenges, competences needed to address them, and tried-and-tested boosts

By fostering existing cognitive and motivational competences or instilling new ones, boosts make it easier for people to exercise their own agency. The emphasis on agency in the boost approach has both ethical and efficacy dimensions. From an ethical standpoint, individual autonomy and freedom cannot be achieved without nurturing citizens’ agency. From an efficacy perspective, interventions that fail to promote agency – as many nudging interventions do – risk leaving citizens in the dark, unable to take ownership of the process of behaviour change. This lack of agency can have several negative outcomes: non-persistent treatment effects, compensatory negative spillovers, or psychological reactance and backfiring effects (Banerjee et al., Reference Banerjee, Grüne-Yanoff, John and Moseley2024). What is more, failing to engage with and listen to people may undermine trust (Tyler and Blader, Reference Tyler and Blader2003), which, as we have seen, is critical for successful behaviour change.

Boosts can be classified according to the kinds of competences they build or enhance. Digital literacy boosts involve strategies like lateral reading, modelled after the methods used by professional fact checkers to efficiently and effectively assess the credibility of unfamiliar websites, posts or information (Kozyreva et al., Reference Kozyreva, Lorenz-Spreen, Herzog, Ecker, Lewandowsky, Hertwig, Ali, Bak-Coleman, Barzilai, Basol, Berinsky, Betsch, Cook, Fazio, Geers, Guess, Huang, Larreguy, Maertens, Panizza, Pennycook, Rand, Rathje, Reifler, Schmid, Smith, Swire-Thompson, Szewach, van der Linden and Wineburg2024). Risk literacy boosts include experienced simulations of risks that help people understand the temporal and cumulative nature of health risks (Wegwarth et al., Reference Wegwarth, Ludwig, Spies, Schulte and Hertwig2022). Financial literacy boosts might employ simple heuristics to help people understand compound interest and exponential growth (Foltice, Reference Foltice2017) or enable microentrepreneurs to clearly separate business and private accounts with the help of physical analogues (Drexler et al., Reference Drexler, Fischer and Schoar2014). Statistical reasoning boosts might contrast correct solutions with typical biased responses in one-shot (Morewedge et al., Reference Morewedge, Yoon, Scopelliti, Symborski, Korris and Kassam2015) or repeated trials (Franiatte et al., Reference Franiatte, Boissin, Delmas and De Neys2024), or train people to transform complex probability representations into simpler frequency representations (Sedlmeier and Gigerenzer, Reference Sedlmeier and Gigerenzer2001). Health literacy boosts enable people to understand drug labels (Sahm et al., Reference Sahm, Wolf, Curtis, Behan, Brennan, Gallwey and McCarthy2012), recognize and monitor symptoms, and employ simple strategies like using implementation intentions to improve self-regulation (Oettingen et al., Reference Oettingen, Hönig and Gollwitzer2000). Decision-making boosts such as decision trees support decision-making in domains such as finance, medicine, human resources, and science education (Katsikopoulos et al., Reference Katsikopoulos, Şimşek, Buckmann and Gigerenzer2021; Osborne and Pimentel, Reference Osborne and Pimentel2022). Motivation boosts can help to overcome maths anxiety and enable parents and children to engage playfully with maths tasks (Berkowitz et al., Reference Berkowitz, Schaeffer, Maloney, Peterson, Gregor, Levine and Beilock2015).

Boosting can also empower citizens to turn the choice architectures around them into strategic allies, a concept known as self-nudging. In self-nudging, the individual serves as both the nudger and the nudgee, effectively becoming a citizen choice architect. This approach addresses several major objections to nudging in addition to those discussed above, such as concerns about paternalism and the uncertainty and heterogeneity of preferences (Reijula and Hertwig, Reference Reijula and Hertwig2022). An example of self-nudging is the mobile phone app one sec (Grüning et al., Reference Grüning, Riedel and Lorenz-Spreen2023), which empowers users to substantially reduce their social media consumption. (See Herzog and Hertwig, Reference Herzog and Hertwig2025, for a comprehensive review of boosts.)

Boosting involves more than just enhancing people’s competences; it also means shaping the environment to maximize individuals’ ability to use those competences. All behaviours involve an interaction of competences, opportunities, and motivations (Michie et al., Reference Michie, van Stralen and West2011). Competences are only useful to the extent that the environment enables them to be deployed effectively. For example, understanding the importance of ventilating indoor spaces to avoid the spread of airborne viruses is useless if buildings do not allow for windows to be opened. Similarly, understanding the importance of self-isolating when infected with a dangerous pathogen will only get a society so far if citizens lack the necessary economic, practical, and social support to do so.

The need for urgent action

Now is the time to rethink strategies for behaviour change. The deficit model, exemplified by nudging, urgently needs to be replaced by an approach that can achieve the global behaviour changes needed to cope with the multiple crises humanity is currently facing. The things we all do drive pandemics (e.g., travel, meat-rich diets), and therefore the next – potentially more lethal – pandemic could be emerging as we write this. The climate emergency is already claiming countless lives and damaging economies. In conjunction with other challenges, such as biodiversity loss, antimicrobial resistance, democratic backsliding, and global conflicts, humanity’s continued progress may be in jeopardy.

Yet we have the opportunity to build on our achievements as a species and create a society capable of meeting current and future challenges, in which social agents actively shape their futures. The concept of agency – and the recognition that people are empowered to make changes when they act together (Drury and Reicher, Reference Drury and Reicher2009) – marks a critical dividing line between approaches to behaviour change. The problem with the individual deficit model of the nudge approach is that it merely tweaks behaviour at the margins. What is needed are wholesale, sustained, and evidence-based efforts to capitalize on and develop collective human agency.

References

Allington, D., McAndrew, S., Moxham-Hall, V., and Duffy, B. (2023), ‘Coronavirus conspiracy suspicions, general vaccine attitudes, trust and coronavirus information source as predictors of vaccine hesitancy among UK residents during the COVID-19 pandemic’, Psychological Medicine, 53(1): 236247.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Banerjee, S., Grüne-Yanoff, T., John, P., and Moseley, A. (2024), ‘It’s time we put agency into behavioural public policy’, Behavioral Public Policy, 8(4): 789806.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barroso, C., Ganley, C. M., McGraw, A. L., Geer, E. A., Hart, S. A., and Daucourt, M. C. (2021), ‘A meta-analysis of the relation between math anxiety and math achievement’, Psychological Bulletin, 147(2): 134168.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
BBC, (2021), Covid: turning down Covid vaccine is selfish, says Michael Gove. https://www.bbc.co.uk/news/uk-politics-57987016 [ 2020, April 27 ].Google Scholar
Behaviour fuels, and fights, pandemics (2020), Nature Human Behaviour, 4: 435CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benartzi, S., Beshears, J., Milkman, K. L., Sunstein, C. R., Thaler, R. H., Shankar, M., Tucker-Ray, W., Congdon, W. J. and Galing, S. (2017). ‘Should governments invest more in nudging?’, Psychological Science., 28(8): 10411055.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Berkowitz, T., Schaeffer, M. W., Maloney, E. A., Peterson, L., Gregor, C., Levine, S. C., and Beilock, S. L. (2015), ‘Math at home adds up to achievement in school’, Science, 350(6257): 196198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bollyky, T. J., Angelino, O., Wigley, S., and Dieleman, J. L. (2022), ‘Trust made the difference for democracies in COVID-19’, The Lancet, 400(10353): 657.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bonell, C., Michie, S., Reicher, S., West, R., Bear, L., Yardley, L., Curtis, V., Amlôt, R., and Rubin, G. J. (2020), ‘Harnessing behavioural science in public health campaigns to maintain “social distancing” in response to the COVID-19 pandemic: key principles’, Journal of Epidemiology & Community Health, 74: 617619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brennan, J. (2016). Against Democracy, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bucher, T., Collins, C., Rollo, M. E., McCaffrey, T. A., De Vlieger, N., Van der Bend, D., Truby, H., and Perez-Cueto, F. J. A. (2016), ‘Nudging consumers towards healthier choices: a systematic review of positional influences on food choice’, British Journal of Nutrition, 115(12): 22522263.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Burgess, R. A., Osborne, R. H., Yongabi, K. A., Greenhalgh, T., Gurdasani, D., and Kang, G. (2021), ‘The COVID-19 vaccines rush: participatory community engagement matters more than ever’, The Lancet, 397(10268): 810.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cadario, R., and Chandon, P. (2020), ‘Which healthy eating nudges work best? A meta-analysis of field experiments’, Marketing Science, 39(3): 465486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caplan, B. (2008). The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why Democracies Choose Bad Policies, Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chater, N. and Loewenstein, G. (2023), ‘The i-frame and the s-frame: how focusing on individual-level solutions has led behavioral public policy astray’, Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 46: e147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cialdini, R. B. (2007), ‘Descriptive social norms as underappreciated sources of social control’, Psychometrika, 72(2): 263268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dallacker, M., Hertwig, R., and Mata, J. (2019), ‘Quality matters: a meta-analysis on components of healthy family meals’, Health Psychology, 38(12): 11371149.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dallacker, M., Knobl, V., Hertwig, R., and Mata, J. (2023), ‘Effect of longer family meals on children’s fruit and vegetable intake: a randomized clinical trial’, JAMA Network Open, 6(4): e236331.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Davydenko, M., Kolbuszewska, M., and Peetz, J. (2021), ‘A meta-analysis of financial self-control strategies: comparing empirical findings with online media and lay person perspectives on what helps individuals curb spending and start saving’, PLoS ONE, 16: e0253938.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dolby, T., Finning, K., Baker, A., Fowler-Dowd, L., Khunti, K., Razieh, C., Yates, T., and Nafilyan, V. (2022), ‘Monitoring sociodemographic inequality in COVID-19 vaccination uptake in England: a national linked data study’, Journal of Epidemiology & Community Health, 76(7): 646652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drexler, A., Fischer, G., and Schoar, A. (2014), ‘Keeping it simple: financial literacy and rules of thumb’, American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 6(2): 131.Google Scholar
Drury, J. (2018), ‘The role of social identity processes in mass emergency behaviour: an integrative review’, European Review of Social Psychology, 29(1): 3881.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drury, J., Novelli, D., and Stott, C. (2013), ‘Psychological disaster myths in the perception and management of mass emergencies’, Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 43(11): 22592270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drury, J., and Reicher, S. (2009), ‘Collective psychological empowerment as a model of social change: researching crowds and power’, Journal of Social Issues, 65(4): 707725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffy, B., and Allington, D. (2020). The Accepting, the Suffering and the Resisting: the different reactions to life under lockdown. The Policy Institute, King’s College London. https://www.kcl.ac.uk/policy-institute/assets/Coronavirus-in-the-UK-cluster-analysis.pdf.Google Scholar
Farrell, H., Mercier, H., and Schwartzberg, M. (2023), ‘Analytical democratic theory: a microfoundational approach’, American Political Science Review, 117(2): 767772.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foltice, B. (2017), ‘How to decrease the amortization bias: experience vs. rules’, Journal of Financial Education, 43(2): 273293.Google Scholar
Franiatte, N., Boissin, E., Delmas, A. and De Neys, W. (2024), ‘Boosting debiasing: impact of repeated training on reasoning’, Learning and Instruction, 89: 101845.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gigerenzer, G., Gaissmaier, W., Kurz-Milcke, E., Schwartz, L. M., and Woloshin, S. (2007), ‘Helping doctors and patients make sense of health statistics’, Psychological Science in the Public Interest, 8(2): 5396.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Grüning, D. J., Riedel, F., and Lorenz-Spreen, P. (2023), ‘Directing smartphone use through the self-nudge app one sec’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 120(8): e2213114120.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hallsworth, M. (2023), ‘A manifesto for applying behavioural science’, Nature Human Behaviour, 7: 310322.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Halpern, D. (2015). Inside the Nudge Unit: How Small Changes Can Make a Big Difference, London: Random House.Google Scholar
Halvorsrud, K., Shand, J., Weil, L. G., Hutchings, A., Zuriaga, A., Satterthwaite, D., Yip, J. L. Y., Eshareturi, C., Billett, J., Hepworth, A., Dodhia, R., Schwartz, E. C., Penniston, R., Mordaunt, E., Bulmer, S., Barratt, H., Illingworth, J., Inskip, J., Bury, F., Jenkins, D., Mounier-Jack, S., and Raine, R. (2023), ‘Tackling barriers to COVID-19 vaccine uptake in London: a mixed-methods evaluation’, Journal of Public Health, 45(2): 393401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, D. M., and Welch, B. (2010), ‘Debate: to nudge or not to nudge’, The Journal of Political Philosophy, 18(1): 123136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hertwig, R. and Grüne-Yanoff, T. (2017). ‘Nudging and boosting: steering or empowering good decisions’, Perspectives on Psychological Science, 12(6): 973986.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Herzog, S. M., and Hertwig, R. (2025), ‘Boosting: empowering citizens with behavioural science’, Annual Review of Psychology, 76: 851881.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobbes, T. (1651/2016). Leviathan, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Jackson, J., Posch, C., Bradford, B., Hobson, Z., Kyprianides, A., and Yesberg, J. (2020), ‘The lockdown and social norms: why the UK is complying by consent rather than compulsion’, LSE British Policy and Politics Blog, https://blogs.lse.ac.uk/politicsandpolicy/lockdown-social-norms/ [27 April 2020].Google Scholar
Johnson, N. R. (1987), ‘Panic and the breakdown of social order: popular myth, social theory, empirical evidence’, Sociological Focus, 20(3): 171183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joint Committee on Human Rights (2020), Black People, Racism and Human Rights: Eleventh Report of Session 2019–21. House of Commons and House of Lords (Accessed 21 October 2024). https://committees.parliament.uk/publications/3376/documents/32359/default/.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. (2003), ‘Maps of bounded rationality: psychology for behavioral economics’, American Economic Review, 93(5): 14491475.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katsikopoulos, K. V., Şimşek, Ö., Buckmann, M., and Gigerenzer, G. (2021). Classification in the Wild: The Science and Art of Transparent Decision Making, Cambridge: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kniffin, K. M., Narayanan, J., Anseel, F., Antonakis, J., Ashford, S. P., Bakker, A. B., Bamberger, P., Bapuji, H., Bhave, D. P., Choi, V. K., Creary, S. J., Demerouti, E., Flynn, F. J., Gelfand, M. J., Greer, L. L., Johns, G., Kesebir, S., Klein, P. G., Lee, S. Y., Ozcelik, H., Petriglieri, J. L., Rothbard, N. P., Rudolph, C. W., Shaw, J. D., Sirola, N., Wanberg, C. R., Whillans, A., Wilmot, M. P., and van Vugt, M. (2021), ‘COVID-19 and the workplace: implications, issues, and insights for future research and action’, American Psychologist, 76(1): 6377.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kozyreva, A., Lewandowsky, S., and Hertwig, R. (2020), ‘Citizens versus the internet: confronting digital challenges with cognitive tools’, Psychological Science in the Public Interest, 21(3): 103156.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kozyreva, A., Lorenz-Spreen, P., Herzog, S. M., Ecker, U. K. H., Lewandowsky, S., Hertwig, R., Ali, A., Bak-Coleman, J., Barzilai, S., Basol, M., Berinsky, A. J., Betsch, C., Cook, J., Fazio, L. K., Geers, M., Guess, A. M., Huang, H., Larreguy, H., Maertens, R., Panizza, F., Pennycook, G., Rand, D. G., Rathje, S., Reifler, J., Schmid, P., Smith, M., Swire-Thompson, B., Szewach, P., van der Linden, S. and Wineburg, S. (2024), ‘Toolbox of individual-level interventions against online misinformation’, Nature Human Behaviour, 8: 10441052.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lauber, K., Rippin, H., Wickramasinghe, K., and Gilmore, A. B. (2022), ‘Corporate political activity in the context of sugar-sweetened beverage tax policy in the WHO European Region’, European Journal of Public Health, 32(5): 786793.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lenton, T. M., Boulton, C. A. and Scheffer, M. (2022), ‘Resilience of countries to COVID-19 correlated with trust’, Scientific Reports, 12: 75.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Michie, S., van Stralen, M. M., and West, R. (2011), ‘The behaviour change wheel: a new method for characterising and designing behaviour change interventions’, Implementation Science, 6: 42.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Morewedge, C. K., Yoon, H., Scopelliti, I., Symborski, C. W., Korris, J. H., and Kassam, K. S. (2015), ‘Debiasing decisions: improved decision making with a single training intervention’, Policy Insights from the Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 2(1): 129140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nestle, M. (2015). Soda Politics: Taking on Big Soda (And Winning), Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Oettingen, G., Hönig, G., and Gollwitzer, P. M. (2000), ‘Effective self-regulation of goal attainment’, International Journal of Educational Research, 33(7–8): 705732.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Osborne, J., and Pimentel, D. (2022), ‘Science, misinformation, and the role of education’, Science, 378(6617): 246248.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Paul, E., Fancourt, D., and Razai, M. (2022), ‘Racial discrimination, low trust in the health system and COVID-19 vaccine uptake: a longitudinal observational study of 633 UK adults from ethnic minority groups’, Journal of the Royal Society of Medicine, 115(11): 439447.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Proctor, K. (2020), ‘UK government’s coronavirus advice—and why it gave it,’ https://www.theguardian.com/world/2020/mar/12/uk-governments-coronavirus-advice-and-why-it-gave-it. (Accessed 21 October 2024).Google Scholar
Reicher, S. D. (2022), ‘After Covid’, IPPR Progressive Review, 29(3–4): 198210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reicher, S. D., and Bauld, L. (2021). ‘From the “fragile rationalist” to “collective resilience”: what human psychology has taught us about the COVID-19 pandemic and what the COVID-19 pandemic has taught us about human psychology’, Journal of the Royal College of Physicians of Edinburgh, 51(S1): S12S19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reijula, S., and Hertwig, R. (2022), ‘Self-nudging and the citizen choice architect’, Behavioral Public Policy, 6(1): 119149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sahm, L. J., Wolf, M. S., Curtis, L. M., Behan, R., Brennan, M., Gallwey, H., and McCarthy, S. (2012), ‘What’s in a label? An exploratory study of patient-centered drug instructions’, European Journal of Clinical Pharmacology, 68(5): 777782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sedlmeier, P., and Gigerenzer, G. (2001), ‘Teaching Bayesian reasoning in less than two hours’, Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 130(3): 380400.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Simmonds, M., Llewellyn, A., Owen, C. G., and Woolacott, N. (2016), ‘Predicting adult obesity from childhood obesity: a systematic review and meta-analysis’, Obesity Reviews, 17(2): 95107.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Simon, H. A. (1956), ‘Rational choice and the structure of the environment’, Psychological Review, 63(2): 129138.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Simon, H. A. (1983). Reason in Human Affairs, Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Somin, I. (2016). Democracy and Political Ignorance: Why Smaller Government Is Smarter, Second Edition, Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Stevenson, C., Wakefield, J. R. H., Felsner, I., Drury, J., and Costa, S. (2021), ‘Collectively coping with coronavirus: local community identification predicts giving support and lockdown adherence during the COVID‐19 pandemic’, British Journal of Social Psychology, 60(4): 14031418.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stewart, H. and Sample, I. (2020), ‘Coronavirus: enforcing UK lockdown one week earlier “could have saved 20,000 lives”’, The Guardian, 11 June.Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. (2022), ‘The distributional effects of nudges’, Nature Human Behaviour, 6: 910.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sunstein, C. R. (2024). ‘AI, reducing internalities and externalities’, SSRN Electronic Journal, https://ssrn.com/abstract=4817483, (Accessed 21 October 2024).Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1991). Quasi-Rational Economics, New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., and Sunstein, C. R. (2003), ‘Libertarian paternalism’, American Economic Review, 93(2): 175179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H., and Sunstein, C. R. (2021). Nudge: The Final Edition, New Haven: Penguin.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., Sunstein, C. R., and Balz, J. P. (2013). Choice architecture. In The Behavioral Foundations of Public Policy, Shafir, E. ed., Princeton: Princeton University Press, 428439.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
The Telegraph (2020). Watch again: Boris Johnson says government is moving towards ‘delay phase’ of coronavirus, YouTube, https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=Yc1alOEjDVA, (Accessed 21 October 2024).Google Scholar
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D. (1974), ‘Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases’, Science, 185(4157): 11241131.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tyler, T. R., and Blader, S. L. (2003), ‘The group engagement model: procedural justice, social identity, and cooperative behavior’, Personality and Social Psychology Review, 7(4): 349361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
UK Covid-19 Inquiry (2023). Public hearings, Module 2, Transcript available at: https://ukcovid19inquiry.dracos.co.uk/module-2/2023-11-28/#mr-michael-gove, [ 2023, 28 November].Google Scholar
Van Bavel, J. J., Cichocka, A., Capraro, V., Sjåstad, H., Nezlek, J. B., Pavlović, T., Alfano, M., Gelfand, M. J., Azevedo, F., Birtel, M. D., Cislak, A., Lockwood, P. L., Ross, R. M., Abts, K., Agadullina, E., Aruta, J. J. B., Besharati, S. N., Bor, A., Choma, B. L., Crabtree, C. D., Cunningham, W. A., De, K., Ejaz, W., Elbaek, C. T., Boggio, P. S. et al (2022), ‘National identity predicts public health support during a global pandemic’, Nature Communications, 13: 517.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Viskupič, F., Wiltse, D. L., and Meyer, B. A. (2022), ‘Trust in physicians and trust in government predict COVID‐19 vaccine uptake’, Social Science Quarterly, 103(3): 509520.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wegwarth, O., Ludwig, W.-D., Spies, C., Schulte, E., and Hertwig, R. (2022), ‘The role of simulated-experience and descriptive formats on perceiving risks of strong opioids: a randomized controlled trial with chronic noncancer pain patients’, Patient Education and Counseling, 105(6): 15711580.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wineburg, S., Breakstone, J., McGrew, S., Smith, M. D., and Ortega, T. (2022), ‘Lateral reading on the open Internet: a district-wide field study in high school government classes’, Journal of Educational Psychology, 114(5): 893909.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Six examples of global challenges, competences needed to address them, and tried-and-tested boosts