Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-9klzr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T17:51:13.086Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The strength of weak leaders: an experiment on social influence and social learning in teams

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Berno Buechel*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Fribourg, Bd. de Pérolles 90, 1700 Fribourg, Switzerland
Stefan Klößner*
Affiliation:
Saarland University, Saarbrücken, Germany
Martin Lochmüller*
Affiliation:
University of Hamburg, Hamburg, Germany
Heiko Rauhut*
Affiliation:
University of Zurich, Zurich, Switzerland

Abstract

We investigate how the selection process of a leader affects team performance with respect to social learning. We use a laboratory experiment in which an incentivized guessing task is repeated in a star network with the leader at the center. Leader selection is either based on competence, on self-confidence, or made at random. In our setting, teams with random leaders do not underperform. They even outperform teams with leaders selected on self-confidence. Hence, self-confidence can be a dangerous proxy for competence of a leader. We show that it is the declaration of the selection procedure which makes non-random leaders overly influential. To investigate the opinion dynamics, we set up a horse race between several rational and naïve models of social learning. The prevalent conservatism in updating, together with the strong influence of the team leader, imply an information loss since the other team members’ knowledge is not sufficiently integrated.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2019 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-019-09614-1) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

We thank Arun Advani, Sandro Ambuehl, Vincent Buskens, Arun Chandrasekhar, Syngjoo Choi, P.J. Healy, Holger Herz, Matt Jackson, Bernhard Kittel, Michael Kosfeld, Jan Lorenz, Friederike Mengel, Claudia Neri, Muriel Niederle, and Tanya Rosenblat for helpful comments. Berno Buechel gratefully acknowledges the hospitality of the Economics Department of Stanford University and the financial support by the Fritz Thyssen Foundation. Heiko Rauhut acknowledges support by the SNSF Starting Grant BSSGI0_155981.

References

Acemoglu, D, Bimpikis, K, & Ozdaglar, A (2014). Dynamics of information exchange in endogenous social networks. Theoretical Economics, 9, 4197. 10.3982/TE1204CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D, Ozdaglar, A, & ParandehGheibi, A (2010). Spread of (mis)information in social networks. Games and Economic Behavior, 70, 194227. 10.1016/j.geb.2010.01.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ambuehl, S, & Li, S (2018). Belief updating and the demand for information. Games and Economic Behavior, 109, 2139. 10.1016/j.geb.2017.11.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, RJ (1976). Agreeing to disagree. The Annals of Statistics, 4(6), 12361239. 10.1214/aos/1176343654CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battiston, P, & Stanca, L (2015). Boundedly rational opinion dynamics in social networks: Does indegree matter?. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 119, 400421. 10.1016/j.jebo.2015.08.013CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, P, Brunnermeier, MK, & Veldkamp, L (2013). Leadership, coordination, and corporate culture. The Review of Economic Studies, 80, 512537. 10.1093/restud/rds041CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J, Giritligil, AE, & Weber, RA (2015). An experimental study of persuasion bias and social influence in networks. European Economic Review, 80, 214229. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2015.07.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Çelen, B, Kariv, S, & Schotter, A (2010). An experimental test of advice and social learning. Management Science, 56, 16871701. 10.1287/mnsc.1100.1228CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandrasekhar, A. G., Larreguy, H., & Xandri, J. P. (2015). Testing models of social learning on networks: Evidence from a lab experiment in the field. National Bureau of Economic Research: Technical report.Google Scholar
Choi, S, Gale, D, & Kariv, S (2005). Behavioral aspects of learning in social networks: An experimental study. Advances in Applied Microeconomics, 13, 2561. 10.1016/S0278-0984(05)13002-8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corazzini, L, Pavesi, F, Petrovich, B, & Stanca, L (2012). Influential listeners: An experiment on persuasion bias in social networks. European Economic Review, 56, 12761288. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2012.05.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeGroot, MH (1974). Reaching a consensus. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 69, 118121. 10.1080/01621459.1974.10480137CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeMarzo, PM, Vayanos, D, & Zwiebel, J (2003). Persuasion bias, social influence, and unidimensional opinions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 909968. 10.1162/00335530360698469CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B. S., & Osterloh, M. (2016). Aleatoric Democracy. CESifo Group Munich: Technical report.Google Scholar
Friedkin, NE (1991). Theoretical Foundations for Centrality Measures. The American Journal of Sociology, 96, 14781504. 10.1086/229694CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedkin, NE, & Johnsen, EC (1990). Social influence and opinions. Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 15, 193206. 10.1080/0022250X.1990.9990069CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gale, D, & Kariv, S (2003). Bayesian learning in social networks. Games and Economic Behavior, 45, 329346. 10.1016/S0899-8256(03)00144-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gervais, S, & Goldstein, I (2007). The positive effects of biased self-perceptions in firms. Review of Finance, 11, 453496. 10.1093/rof/rfm022CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golub, B, & Jackson, MO (2010). Naïve Learning in Social Networks and the Wisdom of Crowds. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2, 112–49.Google Scholar
Grimm, V, & Mengel, F (2018). An experiment on belief formation in networks. Journal of the European Economic Association, 10.1093/jeea/jvy038CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haslam, SA, McGarty, C, Brown, PM, Eggins, RA, Morrison, BE, & Reynolds, KJ (1998). Inspecting the emperor’s clothes: Evidence that random selection of leaders can enhance group performance. Group Dynamics: Theory, Research, and Practice, 2, 168184. 10.1037/1089-2699.2.3.168CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herz, H, Schunk, D, & Zehnder, C (2014). How do judgmental overconfidence and overoptimism shape innovative activity?. Games and Economic Behavior, 83, 123. 10.1016/j.geb.2013.11.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keuschnigg, M, & Ganser, C (2017). Crowd wisdom relies on agents’ ability in small groups with a voting aggregation rule. Management Science, 63, 818828. 10.1287/mnsc.2015.2364CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lorenz, J, Rauhut, H, Schweitzer, F, & Helbing, D (2011). How social influence can undermine the wisdom of crowd effect. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108, 90209025. 10.1073/pnas.1008636108CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mannes, AE (2009). Are we wise about the wisdom of crowds? The use of group judgments in belief revision. Management Science, 55, 12671279. 10.1287/mnsc.1090.1031CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mannes, AE, & Moore, DA (2013). A Behavioral Demonstration of Overconfidence in Judgment. Psychological Science, 24, 11901197. 10.1177/0956797612470700CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mobius, M., Phan, T., & Szeidl, A. (2015). Treasure hunt: Social learning in the field (No. w21014). National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Möbius, M. M., Niederle, M., Niehaus, P., & Rosenblat, T. S. (2011). Managing self-confidence: Theory and experimental evidence. National Bureau of Economic Research: Technical report.Google Scholar
Moore, DA, & Healy, PJ (2008). The trouble with overconfidence. Psychological Review, 115, 502517. 10.1037/0033-295X.115.2.502CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Moussaïd, M, Kämmer, JE, Analytis, PP, & Neth, H (2013). Social influence and the collective dynamics of opinion formation. PloS One, 8, 18.Google ScholarPubMed
Mueller-Frank, M (2013). A general framework for rational learning in social networks. Theoretical Economics, 8, 140. 10.3982/TE1015CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peterson, CR, & Beach, LR (1967). Man as an intuitive statistician. Psychological Bulletin, 68, 29 10.1037/h0024722CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rauhut, H, & Lorenz, J (2011). The wisdom of crowds in one mind: How individuals can simulate the knowledge of diverse societies to reach better decisions. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 55, 191197. 10.1016/j.jmp.2010.10.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, D, Solan, E, & Vieille, N (2009). Informational externalities and emergence of consensus. Games and Economic Behavior, 66, 979994. 10.1016/j.geb.2008.09.027CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soll, JB, & Klayman, J (2004). Overconfidence in interval estimates. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 30, 299.Google ScholarPubMed
Surowiecki, J (2004). The wisdom of crowds, New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Zeitoun, H, Osterloh, M, & Frey, BS (2014). Learning from ancient Athens: Demarchy and corporate governance. The Academy of Management Perspectives, 28, 114. 10.5465/amp.2012.0105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Buechel et al. supplementary material

Buechel et al. supplementary material
Download Buechel et al. supplementary material(File)
File 1.7 MB