Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-f9bf7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T13:09:25.037Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The impact of taxes and wasteful government spending on giving

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Roman M. Sheremeta
Affiliation:
Weatherhead School of Management, Case Western Reserve University, 11119 Bellflower Road, Cleveland, OH 44106, USA Economic Science Institute, Chapman University, One University Drive, Orange, CA 92866, USA
Neslihan Uler*
Affiliation:
Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Maryland, 7998 Regents Dr, College Park, MD 20742, USA

Abstract

We examine how taxes impact charitable giving and how this relationship is affected by the degree of wasteful government spending. In our model, individuals make donations to charities knowing that the government collects a flat-rate tax on income (net of charitable donations) and redistributes part of the tax revenue. The rest of the tax revenue is wasted. The model predicts that a higher tax rate increases charitable donations. Surprisingly, the model shows that a higher degree of waste decreases donations (when the elasticity of marginal utility with respect to consumption is high enough). We test the model’s predictions using a laboratory experiment with actual donations to charities and find that the tax rate has an insignificant effect on giving. The degree of waste, however, has a large, negative and highly significant effect on giving.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2020 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-020-09673-9) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Alm, J, Martinez-Vazquez, J, & McClellan, C (2016). Corruption and firm tax evasion. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 124, 146163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, LR, Mellor, JM, & Milyo, J (2008). Inequality and public good provision: An experimental analysis. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 37(3), 10101028.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J (1989). Giving with impure altruism: Application to charity and ricardian equivalence. The Journal of Political Economy, 97, 14471458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving. Economic Journal, 100, 464477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J (1993). An experimental test of public-goods crowding out hypothesis. American Economic Review, 83, 13171327.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J (2006). Philanthropy: Handbook of giving, reciprocity and altruism, Amsterdam: North Holland 12011269.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J, & Miller, J (2002). Giving according to GARP: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70, 737753.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J, Payne, A Auerbach, A, Chetty, R, Feldstein, M, & Saez, E (2013). Charitable giving. Handbook of public economics, Amsterdam: North Holland 150.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J, & Vesterlund, L (2001). Which is the fair sex? Gender differences in altruism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 293312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auten, GE, Clotfelter, C, Schmalbeck, RL, & Slemrod, J (2000). Taxes and philanthropy among the wealthy. Does atlas shrug? The economic consequences of taxing the rich, New York: Russell Sage 392424.Google Scholar
Auten, GE, Sieg, H, & Clotfelter, CT (2002). Charitable giving, income, and taxes: An analysis of panel data. American Economic Review, 92, 371382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bakija, J, & Heim, B (2011). How does charitable giving respond to incentives and income? New estimates from panel data. National Tax Journal, 64, 615650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barone, G, & Mocetti, S (2011). Tax morale and public spending inefficiency. International Tax and Public Finance, 18, 724749.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergstrom, T, Blume, L, & Varian, H (1986). On the private provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 29, 2549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blumenthal, M, Kalambokidis, L, & Turk, A (2012). Subsidizing charitable contributions with a match instead of a deduction: What happens to donations and compliance?. National Tax Journal, 65, 91116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G, & Katok, E (1998). An experimental test of the crowding out hypothesis: The nature of beneficent behavior. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 37, 315331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buckley, E, & Croson, R (2006). Income and wealth heterogeneity in the voluntary provision of linear public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 935955.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chan, KS, Mestelman, S, Moir, R, & Muller, RA (1996). The voluntary provision of public goods under varying income distributions. Canadian Journal of Economics, 29, 5469.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chan, KS, Mestelman, S, Moir, R, & Muller, RA (1999). Heterogeneity and the voluntary provision of public goods. Experimental Economics, 2, 530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Grosskopf, B (2001). Relative payoffs and happiness: An experimental study. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 45, 301328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clotfelter, CT (1985). Federal tax policy and charitable giving, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clotfelter, CT, & Slemrod, J (1990). The impact of tax reform on charitable giving: A 1989 perspective. Do taxes matter, Cambridge: MIT Press 203235.Google Scholar
Davis, DD, & Millner, EL (2005). Rebates and matches and consumer behavior. Southern Economic Journal, 72, 410421.Google Scholar
Davis, DD, Millner, EL, & Reilly, RJ (2005). Subsidy schemes and charitable contributions: A closer look. Experimental Economics, 8, 85106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duquette, N (2016). Do tax incentives affect charitable contributions? Evidence from public charities’ reported revenues. Journal of Public Economics, 137, 5169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duquette, N., & Hargaden, E. (2019). Inequality and giving. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Eckel, CC, & Grossman, PJ (2003). Rebate versus matching: Does how we subsidize charitable contributions matter?. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 681701.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, CC, Grossman, PJ Davis, D, & Isaac, M (2006). Do donors care about subsidy type? An experimental study. Research in experimental economics, New York: JAI Press 163182.Google Scholar
Eckel, CC, & Grossman, PJ (2006). Subsidizing charitable giving with rebates or matching: Further laboratory evidence. Southern Economic Journal, 72, 794807.Google Scholar
Eckel, CC, & Grossman, PJ (2008). Subsidizing charitable contributions: A natural field experiment comparing matching and rebate subsidies. Experimental Economics, 11, 234252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, CC, Grossman, PJ, & Johnston, R (2005). An experimental test of the crowding out hypothesis. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 15431560.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, CC, Grossman, PJ, & Milano, A (2007). Is more information always better? An experimental study of charitable giving and hurricane Katrina. Southern Economic Journal, 74, 388411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erkal, N, Gangadharan, L, & Nikiforakis, N (2011). Relative earnings and giving in a real-effort experiment. American Economic Review, 101, 33303348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Filiz-Ozbay, E, & Uler, N (2019). Demand for giving to multiple charities: An experimental analysis. Journal of European Economic Association, 17, 725753.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: Organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1, 114125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huck, S, & Rasul, I (2011). Matched fundraising: Evidence from a natural field experiment. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 351362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hungerman, D (2014). Public goods, hidden income, and tax evasion: Some nonstandard results from the warm-glow model. Journal of Development Economics, 109, 188202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hungerman, D., & Ottoni-Wilhelm, M. (2018). Impure Impact giving: Theory and evidence. Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karlan, D, & List, JA (2007). Does price matter in charitable giving? Evidence from a large-scale natural field experiment. American Economic Review, 97, 17741793.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krasteva, S, & Yildirim, H (2016). Information, competition and the quality of charities. Journal of Public Economics, 144, 6477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levitt, SD, & List, JA (2007). What do laboratory experiments measuring social preferences reveal about the real world?. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21, 153174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, SX, Eckel, CC, Grossman, PJ, & Brown, TL (2011). Giving to government: Voluntary taxation in the lab. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 11901201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
List, J (2011). The market for charitable giving. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25, 157180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maurice, J, Rouaix, A, & Willinger, M (2013). Income redistribution and public good provision: An experiment. International Economic Review, 54, 957975.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirrlees, JA (1971). An exploration in the theory of optimal income taxation. Review of Economic Studies, 38, 175208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peloza, J, & Steel, P (2005). The price elasticities of charitable contributions: A meta-analysis. Journal of Public Policy & Marketing, 24(2), 260272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Randolph, W (1995). Dynamic income, progressive taxes, and the timing of charitable contributions. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 709738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rey-Biel, P, Sheremeta, RM, Uler, N Gunnthorsdottir, A, Norton, D, & Caprar, DV (2018). When income depends on performance and luck: The effects of culture and information on giving. Experimental economics and culture, Bingley: Emerald Publishing 167203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saez, E, Slemrod, J, & Giertz, SH (2012). The elasticity of taxable income with respect to marginal tax rates: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 50, 350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, R, & Ockenfels, A (1998). An experimental solidarity game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 34, 517539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seltzer, N. (2009). 1,014 GRE practice questions. Princeton Review.Google Scholar
Silverman, D, Slemrod, J, & Uler, N (2014). Distinguishing the role of authority “In” and authority “To”. Journal of Public Economics, 113, 3242.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uler, N (2009). Public goods provision and redistributive taxation. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 440453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uler, N (2011). Charitable giving, inequality, and taxes. Experimental Economics, 14, 287306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vesterlund, L Kagel, John, & Roth, Alvin (2016). Voluntary giving to public goods: moving beyond the linear voluntary contribution mechanism. Handbook of experimental economics, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Warr, PG (1983). The private provision of a public good is independent of the distribution of income. Economics Letters, 13, 207211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Sheremeta and Uler supplementary material

Sheremeta and Uler supplementary material
Download Sheremeta and Uler supplementary material(File)
File 430.4 KB