Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-nzzs5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T21:28:55.065Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

How Applicable is the Dominant Firm Model of Price Leadership?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Stephen J. Rassenti*
Affiliation:
Interdisciplinary Center for Economic Science, George Mason University, 4400 University Drive, MSN 1B2, Fairfax, VA 22030, USA
Bart J. Wilson*
Affiliation:
Interdisciplinary Center for Economic Science, George Mason University, 4400 University Drive, MSN 1B2, Fairfax, VA 22030, USA

Abstract

In this paper, we examine the usefulness of the dominant firm model of price leadership to serve as a benchmark for organizing behavior in laboratory markets. This well established model, whose origins can be traced back over a hundred years, has been recently applied to such landmark antitrust cases as Standard Oil and Alcoa and more recently to the analysis of deregulated markets for electric power. Our results indicate that in posted offer markets the dominant firm quite often produces more than the model's benchmark and sometimes at much greater prices. With sealed offer auction rules and a low elasticity of fringe supply, the dominant firm produces the theoretical output at a price greater than the prediction. However, with a high elasticity of fringe supply, the dominant firm produces more output over a wide range of prices that includes the predicted price.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2004 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Auspitz, R. and Lieben, R. (1889). “Untersuchungen uber die Theorie des Preises. Leipzig: Verlag von Duncker and Humbolt, 1889.” (Facsimile edition, Düsseldorf, Germany: Verlag Wirtschaft und Finanzen, 1993.).Google Scholar
Borenstein, S., Bushnell, J., and Stoft, S. (2000). “The Competitive Effects of Transmission Capacity in a Deregulated Electricity Industry.” Rand Journal of Economics. 31(2), 294325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borenstein, S. and Bushnell, J. (1999). “An Empirical Analysis of the Potential for Market Power in California's Electricity Industry.” Journal of Industrial Economics. 47, 285324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlton, D. and Perloff, J. (1994). Modern Industrial Organization, 2nd edition. New York: HarperCollins College Publishers.Google Scholar
Davis, D. and Holt, C. (1994). “Market Power in Laboratory Markets with Posted Prices.” Rand Journal of Economics. 25, 467487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, D. and Wilson, B. (2000). “Firm-Specific Cost Savings and Market Power.” Economic Theory. 16(3), 545565.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deneckere, R. and Kovenock, D. (1992). “Price Leadership.” Review of Economic Studies. 59(1), 143162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forchheimer, K. (1908). “Theoretisches zum Unvollständigen Monopole.” Schmollers Jahrbuch. 112.Google Scholar
Holt, C. and Solis-Soberon, F. (1992). “The Calculation of Mixed-Strategy Equilibria in Posted offer Markets.” In Isaac, R.M. (ed.), Research in Experimental Economics, vol. 5. Greenwich: JAI Press.Google Scholar
Klemperer, P. and Meyer, M. (1989). “Supply Function Equilibria in Oligopoly under Uncertainty.” Econometrica. 57, 12431277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kruse, J., Rassenti, S., Reynolds, S., and Smith, V. (1994). “Bertrand-Edgeworth Competition in Experimental Markets.” Econometrica. 62, 343371.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laird, N.M. and Ware, J.H. (1982). “Random-Effects Models for Longitudinal Data.” Biometrics. 38, 963974.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Landes, W. and Posner, R. (1981). “Market Power in Antitrust Cases.” Harvard Law Review. 94, 937996.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Longford, N.T. (1993). Random Coefficient Models. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nichol, A.J. (1930). Partial Monopoly and Price Leadership: A Study in Economic Theory. Philadephia: Press of Smith-Edwards Co.Google Scholar
Rassenti, S., Smith, V., and Wilson, B. (2004). “Strategic Behavior and Hysteresis in Electricity Networks.” Working Paper, Interdisciplinary Center for Economic Science, George Mason University.Google Scholar
Scherer, F.M. (1970). Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance. Chicago: Rand McNally & Company.Google Scholar
Schmidt, T. and Brown, B. (2000). “Imperfect Competition in Auspitz and Lieben (1889).” mimeo, University of New Hampshire, November.Google Scholar
Suslow, V. (1986). “Estimating Monopoly Behavior with Competitive Recycling: An Application to Alcoa.” Rand Journal of Economics. 17, 389403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Utton, M.A. (1995). Market Dominance and Antitrust Policy. Brookfield, VT: Elgar Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Wilson, B. (1998). “What Collusion? Unilateral Market Power as a Catalyst for Countercyclical Markups.” Experimental Economics. 1, 133145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar