Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-g9frx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T17:16:44.581Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Hot Versus Cold Effect in a Simple Bargaining Experiment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Jeannette Brosig
Affiliation:
Faculty of Economics and Management, Otto-von-Guericke-Universität Magdeburg, Germany
Joachim Weimann*
Affiliation:
Faculty of Economics and Management, Otto-von-Guericke-Universität Magdeburg, Germany
Chun-Lei Yang
Affiliation:
ISSP, Academia Sinica, Taiwan, Republic of China

Abstract

In this paper, the strategy method's impact on behavior in sequential bargaining games is investigated. Besides the decision procedure (hot versus cold), we varied the second mover punishment costs (high versus low). Significant impacts of both treatment variables were observed. For example, second movers punished significantly more often in the hot version of the low cost game. Furthermore, first mover behavior was significantly different in the hot and cold versions of both games. In the hot games, first mover behavior suggests an expectation of decreased rewards and/or punishments from second movers. We observed, however, no decrease in reward and an increase in punishment. The hot cold variable only informs first movers that the decision procedure used by second movers has changed. Therefore, first mover behavior must be shaped by their perceived assessment concerning how second movers make decisions. We argue that first mover behavior can be explained by the interaction of two well-known psychological effects: the consensus and positive self-image effects.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2003 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alicke, M.D. and Largo, E. (1995). “The Role of the Self in the False Consensus Effect.” Journal of Experimental Social Psychology. 31, 2847.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allison, S.T., Messick, D.M., and Goethals, G.R. (1989). “On Being Better but not Smarter than Others.” Social Cognition. 7, 275296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984). The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic.Google Scholar
Bazerman, M.H., Moore, D.A., Tenbrunsel, A.E., Wade-Benzoni, K.A., and Blount, S. (1999). “Explaining how Preferences Change Across Joint Versus Separate Evaluation.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 39, 4158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., and McCabe, K. (1995). “Trust, Reciprocity, and Social History.” Games and Economic Behavior. 10, 122142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blount, S. and Bazerman, M.H. (1996). “The Inconsistent Evaluation of Absolute Versus Comparative Payoffs in Labor Supply and Bargaining.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 30, 227240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G.E., Brandts, J., and Ockenfels, A. (1998). “Measuring Motivations for the Reciprocal Responses Observed in a Simple Dilemma Game.” Experimental Economics. 1, 207219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G.E. and Ockenfels, A. (2000). “ERC: A Theory of Equity, Reciprocity, and Competition.” American Economic Review. 90, 166193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bosman, R., Sutter, M., and van Winden, F. (2000). “Emotional Hazard and Real Effort in a Power-to-Take Game: An Experimental Study.” Working Paper.Google Scholar
Brandts, J. and Charness, G. (2000). “Hot vs. Cold: Sequential Responses and Preference Stability in Experimental Games.” Experimental Economics. 2, 227238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C.F., Knez, M., and Weber, R.E. (1996). “Virtual Observability in Ultimatum Bargaining and ‘Weak Link’ Coordination Games.” Experimental Economics, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Charness, G. and Rabin, M. (2002). “Understanding Social Preferences with Simple Tests.” Forthcoming in Quarterly Journal of Economics. 117, 817869.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Damasio, A.R. (1994). Descartes’ Error: Emotion, Reason, and the Human Brain. New York: Putnam.Google Scholar
Darley, J.M. and Berscheid, E. (1967). “Increased Liking Caused by the Anticipation of Personal Contact.” Human Relations. 20, 2940.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawes, R.M. (1989). “Statistical Criteria for Establishing a Truly False Consensus Effect.” Journal of Experimental Social Psychology. 25, 117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawes, R.M. (1990). “The Potential Nonfalsity of the False Consensus Effect.” In Hogarth, R.M. (eds.), Insights in Decision Making: A Tribute to Hillel J. Einhorn. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 179199.Google Scholar
Dufwenberg, M. and Kirchsteiger, G. (1998). “A Theory of Sequential Reciprocity.” CentER Discussion Paper No. 9837, Tilburg University.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (1998). “Emotions and Economic Theory.” Journal of Economic Literature. 36, 4774.Google Scholar
Engelmann, D. and Strobel, M. (forthcoming). “The False Consensus Effect Disappears if Representative Information and Monetary Incentives are Given.Experimental Economics.Google Scholar
Falk, A. and Fischbacher, U. (1998). “A Theory of Reciprocity.” Working Paper.Google Scholar
Farwell, L. and Weiner, B. (1996). “Self-Perceptions of Fairness in Individual and Group Contexts.” Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin. 22, 867881.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., Falk, A., and Fischbacher, U. (2000). “Testing Theories of Fairness—Intentions Matter.” Institute for Empirical Research in Economics. University of Zurich. Working Paper No. 63.Google Scholar
Fehr, E. and Schmidt, K. (1999). “A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 114, 817868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, R.H. (1988). Passion within Reason. New York: W.W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Frijda, N.H. (1986). The Emotions. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gueth, W., Huck, S., and Mueller, W. (2001). “The Relevance of Equal Splits in Ultimatum Games.” Games and Economic Behavior. 37, 161169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gueth, W., Huck, S., and Rapoport, A. (1998). “The Limitations of the Positional Order Effect: Can it Support Silent Threats and Non-Equilibrium Behavior?Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 34, 313325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, J. (1993). “The Affections and the Passions. Their Economic Logic.” Rationality and Society. 5, 185202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., McCabe, K.A., and Smith, V.L. (1998). “Behavioral Foundations of Reciprocity: Experimental Economics and Evolutionary Psychology.” Economic inquiry. 36, 335352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaufman, B.E. (1999). “Emotional Arousal as a Source of Bounded Rationality.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 38, 135144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keser, C. and Gardner, R. (1999). “Strategic Behavior of Experienced Subjects in a Common Pool Resource Game.” International Journal of Game Theory. 28, 241252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, J. and Clement, R.W. (1994). “The Truly False Consensus Effect: An Ineradicable and Egocentric Bias in Social Perception.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 67, 596610.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lazarus, R.S. (1991). Emotion and Adaptation. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
LeDoux, J. (1996). The Emotional Brain: The Mysterious Underpinnings of Emotional Life. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Loewenstein, G. (1996). “Out of Control: Visceral Influences on Behavior.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. 65, 272292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. (2000). “Emotions in Economic Theory and Economic Behavior.” American Economic Review. Papers and Proceedings. 90, 426432.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. and Schkade, D. (1999). “Wouldn't it be Nice? Predicting Future Feelings.” In Kahneman, D. et al. (eds.), Well-Being: The Foundations of Hedonic Psychology. New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 85105.Google Scholar
Marks, G. and Miller, N. (1987). “Ten Years of Research on the False-Consensus Effect: An Empirical and Theoretical Review.” Psychological Bulletin. 102, 7290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Messe, L.A. and Sivacek, J.M. (1979). “Predictions of Others’ Responses in a Mixed Motive Game: Self Justification or False Consensus?Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 37, 602607.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, N. and Marks, G. (1982). “Assumed Similarity Between Self and Other: Effect of Expectation of Future Interaction with that Other.” Social Psychology Quarterly. 45, 100105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitzkewitz, M. and Nagel, R. (1993). “Experimental Results on Ultimatum Games with Incomplete Information.” International Journal of Game Theory. 22, 171198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mullen, B., Atkins, J.L., Champion, D.S., Edwards, C., Hardy, D., Story, J.E., and Venderklok, M. (1985). “The False Consensus Effect: A Meta-Analysis of115 Hypothesis Tests.” Journal of Experimental Social Psychology. 21, 263283.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Offerman, T. (2002). “Hurting Hurts More than Helping Helps.” European Economic Review. 46, 423437.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Offerman, T., Sonnemans, J., and Schram, A. (1996). “Value Orientation, Expectations and Voluntary Contributions in Public Goods.” The Economic Journal. 106, 817845.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, M. (1993). “Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics.” American Economic Review. 83, 12811302.Google Scholar
Rapoport, A. (1997). “Order of Play in Strategically Equivalent Games in Extensive Form.” international Journal. of Game Theory. 26, 113136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rapoport, A. and Fuller, M.A. (1998). “Coordination in Noncooperative Three-Person Games under Different Information Structures.” Group Decision and Negotiation. 7, 363382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romer, P.M. (2000). “Thinking and Feeling.” American Economic Review. Papers and Proceedings. 90, 439443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, L., Greene, D., and House, P. (1977). “The ‘False Consensus Effect’: An Egocentric Bias in Social Perception and Attribution Processes.” Journal of Experimental Social Psychology. 13, 279301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A.E. (1995). “Bargaining Experiments.” In Kagel, J.H. and Roth, A.E. (eds.), Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 253348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, R. (1967). “Die Strategiemethode zur Erforschung des eingeschränkt rationalen Verhaltens im Rahmen eines Oligopolexperiments.” In Sauermann, H. (ed.), Beiträge zur experimentellen Wirtschaftsforschung. Tubingen: Mohr, pp. 136168.Google Scholar
Selten, R., Mitzkewitz, M., and Uhlich, G. (1997). “Duopoly Strategies Programmed by Experienced Players.” Econometrica. 65, 517555.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, R. and Ockenfels, A. (1998). “An Experimental Solidarity Game.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 34, 517539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sherman, S.J., Presson, C.C., and Chassin, L. (1984). “Mechanisms Underlying the False Consensus Effect: The Special Role of Threats to the Self.” Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin. 10, 127138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singh, R., Choo, W.M., and Poh, L.L. (1998). “In-Group Bias and Fair-Mindedness as Strategies of Self Presentation in Intergroup Perception.” Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin. 24, 147162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V.L. and Walker, J.M. (1993). “Monetary Rewards and Decision Costs in Experimental Economics.” Economic inquiry. 31, 245261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, S.E. and Brown, J.D. (1988). “Illusion and Well-Being: A Social Psychological Perspective on Mental Health.” Psychological Bulletin. 103, 193210.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wicklund, R.A. amd Gollwitzer, P.M. (1981). “Symbolic Self-Completion, Attempted Influence, and Self Deprecation.” Basic and Applied Social Psychology. 70, 913930.Google Scholar
Yang, Ch.L., Weimann, J., and Mitropoulos, A. (1999). “Bargaining Power in Simple Sequential Games.” Working Paper.Google Scholar
Zajonc, R.B. (1980). “Feeling and Thinking: Preferences Need no Inferences.” American Psychologist. 35, 151175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar