Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-g9frx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T17:59:08.190Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Choosing Bargaining Partners—An Experimental Study on the Impact of Information About Income, Status and Gender

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Håkan Holm*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Lund University, 22007, Lund, Sweden
Peter Engseld*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Lund University, 22007, Lund, Sweden

Abstract

Ultimatum proposals and dictator donations are studied when proposers can choose the income and sex of the responder. Responder attributes generated strong effects in the selection decisions; subjects preferred to send proposals to low-income responders and female responders were much more popular than males. Hence, signals of income and sex appear to be important in deciding with whom to bargain. We also report from an experiment where both responders and proposers could select co-player based on socioeconomic status and gender. Both female responders and proposers were strongly preferred. A weaker tendency was that high status subjects were favored.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2005 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Andreoni, J. and Vesterlund, L. (2001). “Which is the Fair Sex?.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 116(1), 293312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. (1972). “Models of Job Discrimination.” Racial Discrimination in Economic Life. Lexington: Lexington Books, pp. 83102.Google Scholar
Ball, S., Eckel, C., Grossman, P., and Zame, W. (2001). “Status in Markets.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 116(1), 161188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G.S. (1957). The Economics of Discrimination. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Bolton, G.E. and Ockenfels, A. (2000). “ERC: A Theory of Equity, Reciprocity, and Competition.” American Economic Review. 90(1), 166193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Croson, R. and Buchan, N. (1999). “Gender and Culture: International Experimental Evidence from Trust Games.” American Economic Review. 89(2), 386391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cubbitt, R., Starmer, C., and Sugden, R. (1998). “On the Validity of the Random Lottery Incentive System.” Experimental Economics. 1(2), 115131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M. and Muren, A. (2000). “Discrimination by Gender and Political Correctness,” unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Eagly, A.H. (1995). “The Science and Politics of Comparing Women and Men.” American Psychologist. 50, 145158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, C. and Grossman, P. (1996). “Altruism in Anonymous Dictator Games.” Games and Economic Behavior. 16, 181191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, C. and Grossman, P. (2000). “Differences in the Economic Decisions of Men and Women: Experimental Evidence.” In Plott, C. and Smith, V. (eds.), Forthcoming, Handbook of Experimental Results. Elsevier, New York.Google Scholar
Fehr, E. and Schmidt, K. (1999). “A Theory of Fairness, Competition and Cooperation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fershtman, C. and Gneezy, U. (2001). “Trust and Discrimination in a Segmented Society: An Experimental Approach.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 116(1), 351–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fong, C. (2001). “Social Preferences, Self-Interest, and the Demand for Redistribution.” Journal of Public Economics 82, 225246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fong, C. (2004). “Emphatic Responsiveness: Evidence from a Randomized Experiment on Giving to Welfare Recipients.” Unpublished Manuscript.Google Scholar
Forsythe, R., Horowitz, J., Savin, N.E., and Sefton, M. (1994). “Fairness in Simple Bargaining Experiments.” Games and Economic Behavior. 6(3), 347369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, U. and Rustichini, A. (2000). “Pay Enough or Don't Pay at All.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 115(3), 791810.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guth, W., Schmittberger, R., and Schwarze, B. (1982). “An Experimental Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 3, 367388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hauk, E. and Nagel, R. (2001). “Choice of Partners in Multiple Two-Person Prisoner's Dilemma Games.” Journal of Conflict Resolution. 45(6), 770793.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., McGabe, K., Stachat, K., and Smith, V. (1994). “Preferences, Property Rights, and Anonymity in Bargaining Games.” Games and Economic Behavior. 7, 346380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., McGabe, K., and Smith, V. (1996). “Social Distance and Other-Regarding Behavior in Dictator Games.” American Economic Review. 86(3), 653660.Google Scholar
Holm, H. (2000). “Gender Based Focal Points.” Games and Economic Behavior. 32, 292314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holt, C. (1986). “Preference Reversals and the Independence Axiom.” American Economic Review. 76(3), 508515.Google Scholar
Knez, M. and Camerer, C. (1995). “Outside Options and Social Comparison in Three-Player Ultimatum Game Experiments.” Games and Economic Behavior. 10, 6594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Konow, J. (2000a). “Fair Shares: Accountability and Cognitive Dissonance in Allocation Decisions.” American Economic Review. 90(4), 10721091.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Konow, J. (2000b). “Conditional versus Unconditional Altruism : Theory and Evidence.” Working paper, Department of Economics, Loyola Marymount University.Google Scholar
Ortmann, A. and Tichy, L. (1999). “Gender Differences in the Laboratory: Evidence from Prisoner's Dilemma Games.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 39(3), 327339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phelps, E. (1972). “The Statistical Theory of Racism and Sexism.” American Economic Review. 62, 659661.Google Scholar
Prasnikar, V. and Roth, A. (1992). “Considerations of Fairness and Strategy: Experimental Data from Sequential Games.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 107(3), 865888.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A., and Malouf, W.K. (1979). “Game-Theoretic Models and the Role of Information in Bargaining.” Psychological Review. 86, 574594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A., Malouf, W.K., and Murnighan, K. (1981). “Sociological Versus Strategic Factors in Bargaining.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 2, 153177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A. and Murnighan, K. (1982). “The Role of Information in Bargaining: An Experimental Study.” Econometrica. 50(5), 11231142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A. (1995). “Bargaining Experiments.” In Kagel, J. and Roth, A. (eds.), The Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Selten, R. (1967). “Die Strategiemethode zur erforschung des eigeschrank rationalen verhaltens im rahmen eines oligopolexperiments.” In Sauermann, H. (eds.), Beitrage zur experimentellen wirtschaftsforschung. J.C.B. Mohr: Tubingen, pp. 136168.Google Scholar
Solnick, S.J. (1998). “Gender Difference in an Ultimatum Game.” Unpublished Working Paper, University of Miami.Google Scholar
Solnick, S.J. and Schweitzer, M.E. (1999). “The Influence of Physical Attractiveness and Gender on Ultimatum Game Decisions.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. 79(3), 199215.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Starmer, C. and Sugden, R. (1991). “Does the Random-Lottery Incentive System Elicit True Preferences? An Experimental Investigation.” American Economic Review. 81(4), 971978.Google Scholar
Van Huyck, J. and Battalio, R. (2002). “Prudence, Justice, Benevolence, and Sex: Evidence from Similar Bargaining Games.” Journal of Economic Theory. 104(1), 227246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar