Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-dlb68 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-15T17:12:46.534Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Competing Against Experienced and Inexperienced Players

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Robert L. Slonim*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Case Western Reserve University, 11119 Bellflower Rd., Cleveland, OH 44106

Abstract

In certain markets success may depend on how well participants anticipate the behavior of other participants who have varying amounts of experience. Understanding if and how people's behavior depends on competitors’ level of experience is important since in most markets participants have varying amounts of experience. Examining data from two new experimental studies similar to the beauty contest game first studied by Nagel (1995), the results indicate that (1) players with no experience behave the same against competitors with and without experience but (2) players quickly learn to condition their behavior on competitors’ experience level, causing (3) behavior to stop moving toward the equilibrium whenever new players enter the game and (4) experienced players to earn more money than less experienced players. The paper discusses the implications of the results for understanding and modeling behavior in markets in which participants have different amounts of experience.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2005 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Andreoni, J. (1988). “Why Free Ride? Strategies and Learning in Public Goods Experiments.” Journal of Public Economics. 37, 291304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J. and Miller, J. (1993). “Rational Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoner's Dilemma Game: Experimental Evidence.” Economic Inquiry. 103, 570585.Google Scholar
Bosch-Domenech, A.J., Garcia-Montalvo, R.N., and Sattora, A. (2002). “One, Two(Three)Infinity,…: Newspaper and Lab Beauty-Contest Experiments.” American Economic Review. 92, 16871701.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Budescu, D.I. Erev Wallsten, I., and Yates, T. (Eds.) (1997). “Stochastic and Cognitive Models of Confidence,” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 10.3.0.CO;2-K>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. (1997). “Progress in Behavioral Game Theory.” Journal of Economic Perspectives. 11, 167188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. and Ho, T. (1998). “EWA Learning in Normal-Form Games: Probability Rules, Heterogeneity and Time Variation.” Journal of Mathematical Psychology. 42, 305326.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Camerer, C. and Ho, T. (1999). “Experience Weighted Attractions in Games.” Econometrica. 67, 827874.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C., Ho, T., and Chong, J. (2002a). “Sophisticated EWA Learning and Strategic Teaching in Repeated Games.” Journal of Economic Theory. 104, 137188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C., Ho, T., and Chong, J. (2002b). “Behavioral Game Theory: Thinking, Learning and Teaching.” Working paper, California Institute of Technology.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, D., Feltovich, N., Roth, A., and Zwick, R. (2002). “Relative Versus Absolute Speed of Adjustment in Strategic Environments.” Experimental Economics. 6(2), 181207, forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, D. and Kagel, J. (2002). “Lessons Learned: Generalized Learning Across Games.” American Economic Review. 92(2), 202207.Google Scholar
Croson, R. (1996). “Partners and Strangers Revisited.” Economic Letters. 53, 2532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffy, J. and Nagel, R. (1997). “On the Robustness of Behavior in Experimental Beauty Contest Games.” Economic Journal. 107, 16841700.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M., Lindqvist, T., and Moore, E. (2003). “Bubbles and Experience: An Experiment on Speculation.” Working Paper, University of Arizona.Google Scholar
Erev, I. and Roth, A. (1998). “Predicting How People Play Games: Reinforcement Learning in Experimental Games with Unique Mixed-Strategy Equilibria.” American Economic Review. 88, 848881.Google Scholar
Grosskopf, B. and Nagel, R. (2002). “Rational Reasoning or Adaptive Behavior? Evidence from Two-Person Beauty Contest Games.” Harvard NOM Research Paper No. 01-09.Google Scholar
Haslam, S., Oakes, P., Turner, J., and McGarty, C. (1996). “Social Identity, Self-Categorization, and the Perceived Homogeneity of In-Groups and Out-Groups. The Interaction between Motivation and Cognition.” In Handbook of Motivation and Cognition (vol. 3), Sorrentino, R. and Higgins, E. (eds.), New York: Guilford, pp. 188222.Google Scholar
Harvey, N. (1997). “Confidence in Judgment.” Trends in Cognitive Science. 1, 7882.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ho, T., Camerer, C., and Weigelt, K. (1998). “Iterated Dominance in Iterated Best-Best Response in Experimental P-Beauty Contest Games.” American Economic Review. 88, 947969.Google Scholar
Johnson, E.C. Camerer Sen, S., and Rymon, T. (2002). “Detecting Failures of Backward Induction: Monitoring Information Search in Sequential Bargaining.” Journal of Economic Theory. 104, 1647.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kagel, J. and Levin, D. (1986). “The Winner's Curse and Public Information in Common Value Auctions.” American Economic Review. 76, 894920.Google Scholar
Kagel, J. and Levin, D. (1999). “Common Value Auctions with Insider Information.” Econometrica. 67, 12191238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kagel, J., Levin, D., and Dyer, D. (1989). “A Comparison of Naive and Experienced Bidders in Common Value Auctions: A Laboratory Analysis.” Economic Journal. 99, 108115.Google Scholar
Lichtenstein, S., Fischhoff, B., and Phillips, L. (1982). “Calibration of Probabilities: The State of the Art in 1980.” In Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, Kahneman, D., Slovic, P. and Tversky, A. (eds.), New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 335351.Google Scholar
Nagel, R. (1995). “Unraveling in Guessing Games: An Experimental Study.” American Economic Review. 85, 13131326.Google Scholar
Nagel, R. (1999). “A Survey on Experimental Beauty Contest Games; Bounded Rationality and Learning.” In Games and Human Behavior, Budescu, D., Erev, I. and Zwick, R. (eds.), Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, pp. 105142.Google Scholar
Ockenfels, A. and Roth, A. (2002). “Late and Multiple Bidding in Second Price Internet Auctions: Theory and Evidence Concerning Different Rules for Ending an Auction.” Games and Economic Behavior (forthcoming).Google Scholar
Osborne, M. and Rubinstein, A. (1994). A Course in Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Schotter, A. and Sopher, B. (2003). “Social Learning and Convention Creation in Inter-Generational Games: An Experimental Study.” Journal of Political Economy. 111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, R. and Stoecker, R. (1986). “End Behavior in Sequences of Finite Prisoner's Dilemma Supergames.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 65, 4770.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stahl, D. (1996). “Rule Learning in a Guessing Game.” Games and Economic Behavior. 16, 303330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stahl, D. (2000). “Rule Learning in Symmetric Normal-Form Games: Theory and Evidence.” Games and Economic Behavior 32, 105138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stahl, D. and Wilson, P. (1995). “On Players Models of Other Players.” Games and Economic Behavior. 10, 213254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, R. (2003). “Learning With No Feedback in a Competitive Guessing Game.” Games and Economic Behavior. 44, 134144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar